COCOO CASES

ECT.ARB.berclay.V.spain.uranium.mine

spain.berclay.uranium.mine.arbitration:  Berkeley reclama al Estado 921 millones en su solicitud de arbitraje por la mina de uranio en Salamanca. La compañía inicia el procedimiento ante el Ciadi en una reclamación que sería la mayor que afronta el Gobierno en 20 años.  Berkeley Energia ha informado de la presentación de una solicitud de arbitraje ante el Centro Internacional de Arreglo de Diferencias Relativas a Inversiones (Ciadi), iniciando así el procedimiento contra España respecto de su proyecto de la mina de uranio de Retortillo (Salamanca), en la que pide una compensación preliminar de 1.000 millones de dólares (921 millones de euros). Ya había anunciado recientemente sus intenciones, con un respaldo inmediato en sus acciones de bolsa, y desde entonces no se ha producido ninguna novedad por parte del Gobierno. En un comunicado remitido a la Comisión Nacional del Mercado de Valores (CNMV), la compañía ha informado de que Berkeley Exploration Limited (BEL) ha presentado una solicitud de arbitraje para sus inversiones en España a través de su filial española, Berkeley Minera España (BME), “iniciando el procedimiento arbitraje procedimiento contra el Reino de España ante el Ciadi”. En este sentido, Berkeley defiende que las acciones de España contra su filial española y el proyecto de Salamanca “han violado múltiples disposiciones del Tratado sobre la Carta de la Energía (TCE)” y, como parte de su solicitud de arbitraje, BEL solicita una compensación preliminar del orden de 1.000 millones de dólares (921 millones de euros) por estas infracciones.  “Este arbitraje podría convertirse en la mayor reclamación enfrentada por España desde que José Luis Rodríguez Zapatero fue presidente del Gobierno”, según ha indicado la empresa y recoge Europa Press. La multinacional ha precisado que, después de que el Gobierno español no haya entablado ninguna discusión relacionada con la disputa hasta la fecha, la solicitud de arbitraje ha sido presentada conjuntamente por equipos de especialistas de Herbert Smith Freehills Spain LLP y LCS Abogados, que representarán a BEL en el procedimiento de arbitraje.  De este modo, en la siguiente fase del procedimiento, los miembros del tribunal serán seleccionados y designados y, por lo tanto, quedará establecido formalmente el tribunal.  No obstante, a pesar de la disputa sobre inversiones, BEL ha subrayado que sigue comprometida con el proyecto de Salamanca y continúa abierta a un diálogo constructivo con España, añadiendo que está dispuesta a colaborar con las autoridades españolas pertinentes para encontrar una solución amistosa a la situación de los permisos y mantiene la esperanza de que puedan tener lugar debates en el corto plazo.  Después de conocerse la reclamación de Berkeley ante el Ciadi, los títulos de la compañía repuntaban casi un 5%

Posted by wpMY0dxsz043 in COCOO CASES, 0 comments

THE COCOO GROUP

To align COCOO Ltd’s Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) codes with its role as an independent, non-governmental enforcer of competition law acting in the public and consumer interest, it’s essential to select codes that accurately reflect its activities and support its legal standing (locus standi) in filing claims on behalf of the general public.

Current SIC Codes:

  • 70229: Management consultancy activities other than financial management.
  • 80300: Investigation activities.

newly added SIC Codes:

  1. 6910: Legal Activities
    • This code encompasses legal representation of one party’s interest against another, including:
      • Advice and representation in civil and criminal cases.
      • General counseling and advising.
      • Preparation of legal documents.
    • Applying this code would highlight COCOO Ltd’s legal advocacy and representation functions, reinforcing its capacity to act in legal proceedings concerning public and consumer interests.
  2. 70210: Public Relations and Communications Activities
    • This code covers activities related to public relations and communication strategies.
    • Incorporating this code would reflect COCOO Ltd’s efforts in promoting awareness and advocacy concerning competition law violations affecting the public.

Considerations:

  • Legal Standing (Locus Standi): Selecting SIC codes that emphasize COCOO Ltd’s legal and advocacy roles can strengthen its position when seeking standing in legal actions aimed at protecting public and consumer interests.
  • Regulatory Compliance: Ensure that the chosen SIC codes accurately represent COCOO Ltd’s activities to maintain compliance with regulatory requirements and to support its mission effectively.

By updating COCOO Ltd’s SIC codes to include those related to legal activities and public advocacy, the organization can better align its registered activities with its core mission of enforcing competition law independently and acting in the public interest


HOW TO SET UP COCOO.LTD AS T.S. OF COCOO.UK.CHAR

-JUST file new confirmation statement TO Update the shareholder information, that includes a statement filed by me , as PSC, to reflect that the trust (not I personally) owns the shares.

You Need NOT to Change the PSC: you can stay as the PSC.  Only update the shareholder records, not the PSC register.  If more trustees join, update Companies House

since the charity is a trust and not a corporate entity, the correct approach to updating the Person with Significant Control (PSC) register will depend on whether you, as the sole trustee, still exercise control over COCOO Ltd. Here’s how it works:

 Does the Charity Trust Need to Be Listed as PSC?

No. The charity itself does not need to be listed as a PSC because trusts do not have legal personality—only individuals or legal entities (like companies) can be PSCs

Who Should Be the PSC Now?

✔️ You, as the sole trustee of the charity, should remain as the PSC of COCOO Ltd.
✔️ This is because you, personally, still control the shares on behalf of the trust, and you make all the decisions about the company.
✔️ If the charity had multiple trustees, then all trustees would likely need to be registered jointly as PSCs

 What Needs to Be Filed with Companies House?

Since you are still in control of COCOO Ltd, even though it is owned by the trust, you do not need to file a PSC07 (Cease being a PSC). Instead:

Leave your PSC details as they are, because you still control the company as the sole trustee.
Update the shareholder information in your next Confirmation Statement to reflect that the trust (not you personally) owns the shares.
No need to file PSC03 (for a legal entity as PSC) because the charity is not a corporate body—it’s a trust, meaning it cannot be registered as a PSC

 What If More Trustees Are Appointed in the Future?

If you later appoint additional trustees, then all trustees collectively may become PSCs if they:

  • Control more than 25% of shares or voting rights in COCOO Ltd.
  • Have the power to appoint or remove a majority of the directors.
  • Otherwise exercise significant influence or control over the company.

At that point, you would need to file PSC07 to remove yourself as the sole PSC and file PSC02 (to add multiple trustees as PSCs).


 


-COCOO Ltd may donate its taxable profits to COCOO Charity under the Gift Aid scheme, provided it does not affect the subsidiary’s solvency.

– group structure:

COCOO Ltd (a trading subsidiary) is fully or partially owned by COCOO Charity (a parent charitable entity), is generally a legitimate and common approach for charities to conduct commercial activities while protecting their charitable assets. However, there are several legal and strategic considerations to strengthen the structure and mitigate risks

1. Key Benefits of This Structure

Limited Liability Protection:

  • Since COCOO Ltd is a separate legal entity, any court costs orders or other liabilities incurred in litigation should not affect COCOO Charity or you personally.
  • This is one of the primary benefits of incorporating a limited company as a trading arm.

Regulatory Compliance:

  • Many charities use trading subsidiaries to carry out non-charitable activities (such as litigation) without risking the charity’s tax-exempt status.
  • As long as the trading subsidiary is operated properly and separately, this aligns with charity law principles.

Risk Containment:

  • If COCOO Ltd goes insolvent due to court costs orders, the charity (COCOO Charity) is not automatically liable, unless specific actions (e.g., improper funding, guarantees, mismanagement) compromise separation.

2. Potential Risks and How to Strengthen the Structure

A. Risk of “Piercing the Corporate Veil” (Holding COCOO Charity Liable)

🔹 Risk: Courts can sometimes “pierce the corporate veil” and hold the parent (COCOO Charity) liable if:

  • COCOO Ltd is merely a “sham” or “alter ego” of COCOO Charity.
  • There is no real separation (e.g., shared bank accounts, no independent decision-making).
  • The subsidiary is used to circumvent legal responsibilities (i.e., deliberately avoiding costs orders).

🔹 Solution:
Ensure Clear Legal and Financial Separation

  • Maintain separate bank accounts for COCOO Ltd and COCOO Charity.
  • Have a proper trading agreement between COCOO Ltd and COCOO Charity.
  • Ensure that COCOO Ltd has its own directors and governance separate from the charity.
  • Keep formal records of board meetings and decisions to demonstrate independent operation.

B. Directors’ and Trustees’ Responsibilities

🔹 Risk:

  • If trustees of COCOO Charity also sit on the board of COCOO Ltd, they must ensure no conflicts of interest.
  • If COCOO Ltd becomes insolvent, any personal guarantees given by trustees or directors could expose them personally.

🔹 Solution:
Have a Clear Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) & Conflicts of Interest Policy

  • Ensure COCOO Ltd follows its own corporate governance framework.
  • Set up a conflicts of interest policy for trustees and directors.
  • Appoint at least one independent director to COCOO Ltd’s board to reinforce independence.

C. Funding and Cash Flow Between COCOO Charity & COCOO Ltd

🔹 Risk:

  • If COCOO Charity directly funds COCOO Ltd, there must be a proper agreement to avoid tax and regulatory issues.
  • UK charity law restricts charities from subsidizing private trading subsidiaries unless it is a loan or investment with proper repayment terms.

🔹 Solution:
Use Loans, Not Grants

  • If COCOO Charity provides funding, structure it as a loan at arm’s length.
  • Charge interest to show that the charity is not unlawfully subsidizing the subsidiary.

Ring-fence Charity Assets

  • The charity should avoid guaranteeing COCOO Ltd’s debts, as this would put charitable funds at risk.

Use Gift Aid to Move Profits Up to COCOO Charity

  • If COCOO Ltd makes a profit, it can gift aid its taxable profits to COCOO Charity, reducing corporation tax liability.

D. Court Costs and Insolvency Risk

🔹 Risk:

  • If COCOO Ltd loses multiple cases and cannot pay court costs, it may be liquidated.
  • If COCOO Ltd is seen as undercapitalized (i.e., it has no real financial backing), courts may hold the charity responsible.

🔹 Solution:
Ensure COCOO Ltd Has Sufficient Assets to Cover Its Own Liabilities

  • COCOO Ltd should have some assets or capital to cover court costs.
  • Avoid transferring liabilities back to COCOO Charity.

Use Litigation Insurance or After-the-Event (ATE) Insurance

  • This can cover legal costs in case of a loss, reducing risk.

3. Alternative Ways to Improve the Structure

1️⃣ Consider a Holding Structure

  • Instead of COCOO Charity directly owning COCOO Ltd, you could create an intermediate holding company (COCOO Holdings Ltd).
  • This would provide an additional layer of protection, making it harder for claimants to reach COCOO Charity’s assets.

2️⃣ Use a “Hybrid” Structure with a Community Interest Company (CIC)

  • A CIC is a limited company with a social purpose.
  • Unlike charities, CICs have more freedom in trading activities.
  • This might give COCOO Ltd more credibility in court, while still being separate from COCOO Charity.

3️⃣ Register COCOO Ltd in a Low-Liability Jurisdiction

  • In some cases, setting up COCOO Ltd in a different jurisdiction (e.g., Ireland, the Isle of Man, or the Cayman Islands) can provide further liability protection.

Conclusion

Your proposed structure is fundamentally sound, but there are key areas that need to be strengthened to ensure:

  • COCOO Charity is protected from legal and financial liabilities.
  • COCOO Ltd is properly capitalized and structured to withstand legal risks.
  • Regulatory compliance is met (charity law, tax rules, and corporate governance requirements).

 


It is generally more ethical and professional to approach clients through their firm of solicitors, ensuring you respect the solicitor-client relationship. Direct contact may be lawful in some circumstances, but only if justified, transparent, and handled with caution to avoid undermining professional norms.


business plan
oscar, is an in-house solicitor for Cocoo Ltd, providing legal services to your employer (Cocoo Ltd). Cocoo Ltd, in turn, provides non-reserved legal services to solicitors and/or their clients under a commercial agreement. Since you would not be acting directly for the solicitors’ clients but for your employer, the key considerations include:

1. Compliance with SRA Rules

  • Your Role as In-House Solicitor:
    • You are bound by the SRA Principles and Code of Conduct for Solicitors. Your professional responsibilities are to your employer (Cocoo Ltd) and include ensuring transparency, upholding integrity, and managing risks such as conflicts of interest.
  • Cocoo Ltd’s Role as Legal Services Provider:
    • Cocoo Ltd is not an SRA-regulated entity. This distinction must be made clear to the solicitors and their clients. While Cocoo Ltd can provide non-reserved legal services, these services are not regulated by the SRA, which means they do not carry the same client protections

2. Key Ethical and Practical Considerations

A. Transparency

  • Communication must clarify:
    1. Your role and employer: You act only for Cocoo Ltd.
    2. Nature of the services: Cocoo Ltd provides non-reserved legal services and is not regulated by the SRA.
    3. Limitations of regulatory protections: Clients of Cocoo Ltd should understand that they are not protected by the SRA or the Legal Ombudsman in relation to these services.
  • Ensure that all parties (the solicitors and their clients) are fully informed of the arrangement.

B. Independence

  • While your role is to act for Cocoo Ltd, you must:
    • Maintain independence in your professional judgment.
    • Avoid undue influence by commercial pressures from Cocoo Ltd that might compromise your ethical obligations under the SRA Principles.

C. Conflicts of Interest

  • Even though you act for Cocoo Ltd, ensure there is no indirect conflict of interest:
    • Example: If Cocoo Ltd’s provision of services to a solicitor’s client indirectly conflicts with Cocoo Ltd’s own business interests or the solicitor’s duties to their client.

D. Competence and Scope

  • Ensure that Cocoo Ltd only undertakes non-reserved legal services within its expertise and capacity.
  • Your provision of reserved legal services must strictly be for Cocoo Ltd and not for any third party.

E. Commercial Legal Services Agreement

  • The agreement between Cocoo Ltd and the solicitors (or their clients) should clearly outline:
    • The scope of non-reserved legal services.
    • Fees and payment terms.
    • Limitations of liability.
    • Transparency around Cocoo Ltd’s regulatory status.

3. Is This Arrangement Ethical and Within the Rules?

Yes, provided:

  • All communication is transparent, including disclosures about Cocoo Ltd’s regulatory status and the non-applicability of SRA protections.
  • You maintain your ethical duties as a solicitor, including independence, integrity, and avoiding conflicts of interest.
  • Cocoo Ltd only provides non-reserved legal services (as these can be offered by non-regulated entities).

No, if:

  • There is any lack of clarity or transparency in communication.
  • Cocoo Ltd or you undertake reserved legal services for third parties without appropriate regulatory status or authorisation
Posted by wpMY0dxsz043 in COCOO CASES, 0 comments

cy press distributions

 


Cy Pres Distributions in Class Action Settlements

The cy pres doctrine (from the French phrase cy près comme possible, meaning “as near as possible”) is a legal principle used in U.S. class action settlements when it is impractical to directly distribute damages to all affected class members. This typically happens in situations where:

  1. Class Members Cannot Be Identified or Located: For example, if the harm affects a diffuse group of individuals without clear records or contact information.
  2. Low Individual Recovery Amounts: When individual payouts would be so small (e.g., a few cents per person) that distributing them directly is inefficient.
  3. Unclaimed Funds Remain: After eligible class members have been compensated, leftover funds may still exist.

How Cy Pres Distributions Work

  1. Selection of Beneficiaries:
    • Courts direct leftover settlement funds to organizations, initiatives, or charities that indirectly benefit the class or align with the goals of the litigation.
    • Examples include nonprofits, consumer advocacy groups, academic research initiatives, or public-interest programs relevant to the litigation’s subject.
  2. Legal Oversight:
    • Courts approve cy pres beneficiaries to ensure they serve purposes closely related to the original claims in the case. For example:
      • A class action against a tech company for data breaches might direct funds to organizations focused on cybersecurity education.
      • A consumer fraud case might allocate funds to consumer rights organizations.
  3. Common Examples of Cy Pres Recipients:
    • Educational institutions (e.g., scholarships for studies in law, technology, or ethics).
    • Advocacy groups promoting consumer protection, public safety, or environmental sustainability.
    • Charitable organizations that support victims of similar types of harm (e.g., privacy violations, discrimination, or financial fraud).

Legal Standards for Cy Pres Awards

Courts are careful to ensure that cy pres distributions meet certain criteria:

  1. Nexus to the Case: The recipient must advance interests related to the class’s harm.
  2. Avoidance of Conflicts: Judges and attorneys must not have personal or professional connections to the chosen organizations.
  3. Feasibility: Cy pres awards are used only when direct distribution is infeasible.

Criticism of Cy Pres Doctrine

The doctrine has faced criticism, primarily for the following reasons:

  1. Lack of Direct Benefit to Class Members: Critics argue that class members may receive no tangible compensation.
  2. Potential for Misuse: There is concern that cy pres funds could be directed to organizations favored by attorneys or judges rather than genuinely benefiting the class.
  3. Accountability Issues: Monitoring how funds are used by beneficiaries can be challenging.

Prominent Cy Pres Settlements

  1. Google Privacy Class Action (2019): A $13 million settlement was distributed to privacy advocacy groups after individual payouts to affected users (estimated at pennies per person) were deemed impractical.
  2. Facebook Beacon Settlement (2010): Unclaimed funds from a $9.5 million privacy lawsuit were allocated to a digital privacy foundation.

Benefits of Cy Pres Distributions

Despite criticisms, cy pres awards are a pragmatic solution in cases involving large, unidentifiable, or minimally harmed classes. They:

  1. Ensure that settlement funds serve a purpose rather than being returned to defendants.
  2. Support organizations or causes that align with the litigation’s goals.
  3. Promote long-term benefits by funding research, education, or advocacy to prevent future harms.

 

Posted by wpMY0dxsz043 in COCOO CASES, 0 comments

ALL.FILES



                              

x.grok      

E.CONSUMER.GOV =  a project of the International Consumer Protection and Enforcement Network (ICPEN), is a partnership of more than 65 consumer protection agencies around the world.


GCR.SEARCH    GCR:cartels.mergers.verticalrestraints  >>     GCR.cases&precedents.BESTSEARCH     GCRnews.mergers    GCRnews.colls     GCRnews.antitrust.litig    GCRnews.ADP    GCRnews.CAT    compasslexecon.cases.search       GCR.vertical.restraints   >>   GCR.vertical.restraints.EU.search


-video transcriptors online:    tactiq.io    youtubetranscript.com     youtube-transcript.io
-video trancriptors on wp:   WP >>  VIDEO SEO >> ADD.NEW.ITEM:    vidseo   videseo.settings

COCOO.UK.posts.pages.Sitemap :


https://cocoo.uk/cocoo-v-esp-moro-ec-itas/       https://cocoo.uk/finco-groupfinancing-is-sa/         

https://cocoo.uk/20342-2/


WP.FILE.LIST.PRO   

Name Size Date
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

13 Items
3.15 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

3 Items
1.33 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

1 Items
1.13 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

5 Items
4.23 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

3 Items
2.39 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

1 Items
1.01 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

1 Items
1.78 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

1 Items
76.67 KB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

1 Items
160.89 KB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

5 Items
9.38 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

5 Items
4.84 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

2 Items
1.41 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

1 Items
480.56 KB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

4 Items
3.88 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

5 Items
3.36 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

5 Items
8.62 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

2 Items
1.7 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Zip File Edit Delete Move

15 Items
14.49 MB
06/03/2025
Thumb

Open Download Copy Link Edit Delete Move

436.94 KB 17/06/2023
Thumb

HBER

Open Download Copy Link Edit Delete Move

1.4 MB 25/08/2023
Thumb

VABEO

Open Download Copy Link Edit Delete Move

1.35 MB 25/08/2023

×××××××××××××NON-SCAN PDFS >> DOWNLOAD.LINKS from gdrive××××××××××××

   


WTO.EUrelated.ongoing.ADR.CASES.pdf      wto.2024.report.pdf


COCOO.UK.WEBSITE

WEBSITE CONTENT.1.pdf     WEBSITE.CONTENT.2.pdf    30.7.24 SMARTERBOOKMARKS    COCOOUK.T CODE.pdf    kneepkens BOOK1.PDF
kneepkens BOOK2.PDF   kneepkens BOOK3.PDF
kneepkens BOOK4_2ND, 3RD, 4TH EP CONDITIONS.PDF
KNEEPKENS BOOK5_ RMS FOR MCR.pdf
massimo motta -1.PDF
massimo motta-2.PDF
massimo motta-3.PDF
massimo motta-4.PDF
massimo motta-5.PDF
CARTELS + ADP.PDF
cas mandates.PDF
CLCP.PDF
CLP. types of economies.pdf
CL_ EL.PDF
CL__ cam.co.PDF
how gov impact comp. neutrality.PDF
MERGERS.PDF
UK MERGER CONTROL.PDF


RESEARCH TOOLS

fee sharing agreements.pdf
In-housePracticeGuidance-web-ver1.2 (1).pdf
pap_tec20151217generalapproach.xlsx
pap_tec20151217odi.xlsx
pap_tec20151217retail.xlsx
pap_tec20151217wholesale.xlsx
SIM.xlsx
Specific-CI.xlsx

fee sharing agreements.pdf
In-housePracticeGuidance-web-ver1.2 (1).pdf
pap_tec20151217generalapproach.xlsx
pap_tec20151217odi.xlsx
Specific-CI.xlsx
SIM.xlsx
pap_tec20151217wholesale.xlsx
pap_tec20151217retail.xlsx


strategy.links:

DUTIES + REMEDIES.pdf
HOW COCOO WILL INTERVENE
LIMITATIONS TO SN & freedom of contract.pdf
LPP_CIP.PDF
Mediation-providers-March-2024.pdf
NDA.PDF
RLCM.pdf
RTD. RTEFA. ADP.PDF
strategies.PDF
THIRD PARTY INTERVENTIONS (3PI).pdf
TICKING CLOCK. gelmato strategy.pdf


rns:

rns-pricing-and-policy-guidelines-2024.pdf
RNS FACT SHEET – RNS Submit Quick Step User Guide.pdf
RNS Submit – Multimedia User Guide.pdf
rns terms.pdf


oc.os. :    Oc.all.co.regs   oc.how2.guide

opencorporates how to use
oc os rns parlomb pwds_240608_003447.pdf
oc os rns parlomb pwds_240608_003447.txt


fsa complaionts

aggregate-complaints-data-2023-h2.xlsx
firm-level-complaints-data-2023-h2.xlsx


all.market.definitions (MADs)

AIRLINES .txt
AIRLINES 2.txt
AIRLINES 3.txt
BOOKS.txt
CAR MAKERS VOLVO.txt
CAR MANUFACTURE.txt
CASINOS.txt
CATENARY.NUCLEAR.txt
CHEMICAL ADMIXTURES_240606_173003.pdf
CHEMICALS DISTRIBUTION.txt
CHEMICALS PROD.txt
CHIPSET MANUFACTURE.txt
CLEARING SERVICES TRADES.txt
CLOUD.txt
CNMC:mediaset.txt
COMODITIES.txt
COMPUTERS AND SMART GRID MANUFACTURE.txt
CONSTRUCTION.txt
DIAMONDS.txt
ELECTRIC CAR CHARING STATIONS.txt
ELECTRICIY SUPPLY.txt
ELECTRONIC DISPLAYS MANUFACTURE.txt
EQUITIES TRADING PLATFORMS.txt
FDP PHARMA.txt
GAMING.txt
HIV.txt
IPR.txt
IT SERVICES.txt
IT TYING.txt
MARKET DEFINITION AND MARKET SHARES.PDF
MINING FOR CHEMICALS
MOBILE PHONES MANUF DISTRIB.txt
MUSIC.txt
NUCLEAR SERVICES.txt
NUCLEAR STATIONS BUILDING.txt
OIL.txt
OIL EXTRACTION AND SUPPLY.txt
OIL INFRASTRUCTURE.txt
OIL TRANSPORT.txt
OUTSOURCING.txt
PHARMA 1.txt
PHARMA 2.txt
PLATINUM.txt
POULTRY.txt
PRIVATE HEALTHCARE.txt
PRIVATE HEALTHCARE 2.txt
RUBBER PLASTICS.txt
SATELLITES.txt
SERVERS.txt
SHARES DERIVATIVES TRADING .txt
SIM CARDS.txt
TIMBER PAPER.txt
URANIUM.txt
WEBANALYTICS.txt
WIND TURBINES AND TRADING.txt


BANKS.research.tools:

Bank-Regulatory-Capital-Slides.pdf
Bank-Regulatory-Capital.xlsx
CS-Annual-Report-Extracts.pdf
CS-Annual-Report.pdf
SVB-10-K-Extracts.pdf
SVB-10-K.pdf


ipo

107-09-IPO-Valuation-Model.xlsx


mato

10-12-Income-Statement-Combination-After.xlsx
10-12-Income-Statement-Combination-Before.xlsx
printed.Merger-Model-Interview-Questions.xlsx
printed.Purchase-Price-MA-Deals.xlsx


comparable valuation-type:

107-21-Comparable-Company-Analysis.xlsx


nopat valuation-type:

107-25-DCF-Model-Slides.pdf
107-25-Walmart-10-K-Excerpts.pdf
107-25-Walmart-DCF-Model.xlsx
Best-Buy-10-K-Extracts.pdf
mergersandinquisitions.com-Video Analysis Of Why Uber Is Significantly Overvalued.pdf
NOPAT-ROIC.xlsx
Target-10-K-Extracts.pdf


precendent.valuation-type:

107-27-ALXN-10-K.pdf
107-27-ALXN-10-Q.pdf
107-27-ALXN-Deal-Press-Release.pdf
107-27-ALXN-MA-Comp.xlsx
107-27-JAZZ-Precedent-Transactions.xlsx
107-27-Precedent-Transaction-Analysis-Slides.pdf
107-27-STLD-Precedent-Transactions.xlsx



PPP.USP

Current-PFI-PF2-projects-as-at-31-March-2023.ods
Guidance_ PPP_Contractual_Provisions_EN_2017.pdf
heat-networks-procurement-pipeline-jan-mar-2023-q1.pdf
Hybrid ppp eufund-priv or national funds.pdf
National_Infrastructure_and_Construction_Pipeline_2023.xlsx
PF2-Equity-IRR-Data-as-at-31-March-2023.xlsx
publicsectorclassificationguidelatest.pdf
Template_knowledge_assets_register.xlsx
Uk 50 emerging techs.pdf
vfm_qe_spreadsheet_122011.xls


model contracts:

Model-contract-offered-bt-PB-to-priv_serv_provider.pdf
Model-contract-offered-bt-PB-to-priv_supplier.pdf
Model_Services_Contract_v.2.1_-_Core_Terms__E_W_.docx
Model_Services_Contract_v2.1_-_Guidance__E_W_.pdf
Model_Services_Contract_v2.1_Combined_Schedules__E_W_.docx
Model_Services_Contract_v2_1_Combined_Schedules__E_W_.pdf


eurostat.ons

Decisions – Government finance statistics and EDP statistics – Eurostat
ESA2010.pdf
EUROSTATGuideStatisticalTreatmentPPPs.pdf
ONS.FWP.mar2024.xlsx


asset identification:

7022.pdf
06022020_Government_as_Insurer_of_Last_Resort_report__Final_clean_.pdf
asset_sale_disclosures_guidance_for_government_web.pdf
BEIS_External_Information_Asset_Register.csv
Current-PFI-PF2-projects-as-at-31-March-2023
Exploring_the_UK_government_s_contingent_liabilities_-_June_2022.pdf


ccs:

Buyer-Supplier-Contract-v1.0.docx
CCS-Supplier-Contract-v1.0-1.docx
eSourcing suite customer guidance_0.pdf
RM3786 Optional specialism matrix V2.0.xlsx
RM3786 Panel services V4.0.docx
RM3786-eSourcing-customer-guidance.pdf
RM3786-Supplier-Contact-List-V3.docx
RM3787 Optional specialism matrix.pdf
RM3787 Panel services.pdf
RM3787 Secondment agreement template.docx
RM3787-Panel-tc-v2.pdf
RM6098-Buyer-guide-v6.4
RM6098-Buyer-guide-v6.4.odt
RM6098-Direct-award-procedure-overview-v5.1-1
RM6098-Direct-award-procedure-overview-v5.1-1.odt
RM6237-LVPS-Buyer-Guidance-v3.0.odt
RM6237-LVPS-Supplier-Access-Information_v8.2.odt


LOBBYING:

APPG-advice-on-due-diligence.pdf
appg-guide12-september-2023.pdf
registration-form-for-appgs.docx

PSTW_Dataset.xlsx
PSTW_Metadata.xlsx
PSTW_Taxonomy.xlsx

Consult lobbying breaches.pdf
Lobbying-uk-fines-cases.pdf
ORCL-CurrentRegister2024.pdf
Orcl_-External-Communications-Record.pdf
PAB-REGISTER.pdf
Uk-lobyy-reg.pdf


ONGOING REG.CASES:

Government interventions on national security grou.PDF
Government interventions on public interest ground.PDF
National UK Security and Investment Act—progress trac.PDF
UK competition law—ongoing legislation and policy.PDF
UK Digital Markets Competition regime—progress tra.PDF


WPI.JR

egs of WPI GROUNDS + GOALS.pdf
estimating-the-cost-of-capital.pdf
How Regulators Calculate Price Controls.pdf
Jr
JR UK.pdf
PRECLUSION_ RJ AND RJ DEFENCES.PDF
REGULATION. Wicrs.PDF
the-statutory-framework.pdf
UN _ WPI EXCEPTIONS AND EXEMPTIONS.PDF
WPI. SOUTH AFRICA.pdf
WPI IN MA.pdf
WPIS_ S.9 EXEMPTION. CCAS. CRP. GLP ON ENZF.pdf


ELP

AMAZON_ EU FUNDING + BANKTRACK CHALLENGES.pdf
CLIMATECASECHART.COM.pdf
ELP.pdf
ICC. ecocide.pdf


UK

BAES SHIT.pdf
FR (eu charter) _ firms DEFENCE FROM CAS.pdf
MOD + BAE T.O.+ UNDERTAKINGS REVIEW.pdf

UK TOPANELDISCLTABLE.xls

L+ uk ongoing FOCs.PDF
uk sector analysis 2016.xls

 


CMA

CMA_Prioritisation_Principles__.pdf
UK market studies and market investigation referen.PDF
UK mergers—ongoing cases tracker.PDF

Amazon marketplace commitments.pdf
Baker_Hughes_-_Altus_-_Decision_for_final_acceptance_of_UILs_–.pdf
Bougyes_Equans_decision_for_final_acceptance_of_UILs.pdf
Carpenter_Recticel_Final_Undertakings_-_non-confidential_version.pdf
CLOUD AEC PROPOSED REMEDIES.pdf
Cma monitoring compliance by Lindab.pdf
Decision.pdf
Eville_-_Jones__Full_text_decision_.pdf
Final_Acceptance_of_UILs.pdf
Final_text_decision___.pdf
Final_Undertakings.pdf
Final_Undertakings_take_4_PDFA.pdf
Final_Undertakings__FINAL__REDACTED.pdf
For_publication_-_IVC_-_Non-confidential_decisions_for_final_acceptance_of_UILs_-_30062023_A.pdf
LKQ_Uni-Select_-_Decision_for_final_acceptance_of_UILs_PUBLIC.pdf
Microsoft unders.pdf
NEC_SSS_Final_undertakings.pdf
Osmosis-Firewall_-_Decision_for_final_acceptance_of_UILs-_For_the_Public_.pdf
Pennon_Bristol_-_acceptance_of_UILs.pdf
Sika-MBCC_-_Final_Draft_of_Final_Undertakings__FINAL_-_non-confidential_.pdf

A._Final_undertakings.pdf
Hitachi accepting undertakings.pdf
Hitachi additional undertakings.pdf
Hitachi proposed merger harms uk consumers.pdf
Hitachi rail undertakings.pdf


cma.ONGOING UNDERTAKINGS:

baes-marconi-undertakings-2006.pdf
eads-astrium-uil-02-09-03.pdf
finmeccanica-marconi-strat-comms-unds-28-11-02.pdf
gec-plessey-siemens-unds-02-08-89.pdf
gov-kuwait-bp-unds-23-01-89.pdf
p-and-o-stena-unds-27-02-98.pdf


cma.SAU.SUBSIDY(SA).CONTROL:

Home Green heating standards breaching consumer law.pdf
sau.sdocx
SAU market failures.pdf
UK subsidy control—appeals tracker.PDF
UK subsidy control—cases tracker.PDF



ALP

TI
ALP.pdf
AR_OD.pdf
COCOO v antidemocracy __ ALP.pdf
ILP __ OD.AR.pdf

TI.pdf
TI _ AL __ CL. procurement.pdf
TI_ BORs.pdf
TI_ CC CORRUPTION.pdf
TI_ CLIMATE CORRUPTION_ ART.6 PA. UNFCCC. CDM_.pdf
TI_ corruption in infrastructure (CI).pdf
TI_ DAÑOS SOCIALES DE LA CORR __ DH (HR).pdf
TI_ EU STATES’ ACAS.pdf
TI_ GLOBAL BANKS ANTICORS.pdf
TI_ HOW TO DESTROY CORRUPTION. BEST STRATEGIES.pdf
TI_ IDENTIFYING IFFs.pdf
TI_ ISA AL .BEST STRATEGIES.pdf
TI_ legislative discretionary spending [LDS]. CDFs.pdf
TI_ LOBBYING = SIGs = DONATIONS = BRIBES.pdf
TI_ MDBs.pdf
TI_ NCC. NCF. AR. BEST STRATEGIES.pdf
TI_ NGOS V IFFs – CIFAR. germany. sa_.pdf
TI_ NR CORR.pdf
TI_ PP __ CLCP.pdf
TI_ Prosecuting corr in Eu_UK.pdf
TI_ public debarment lists.pdf
TI_ SAIs.pdf
TI_ TAs= FTAs.pdf
TI_ techs to prove ML.pdf

EU behavioural investigations—ongoing cases tracke.PDF
EU CIF JR.PDF
EU competition law—legislation and policy tracker.PDF
EU INFO SOURCES .PDF
General Court Digital Markets Act appeals—ongoing.PDF
LATEST.EC.DECISIONS.csv
Nov 23. Ec soo amazon irobot.pdf
UK EU Merger decisions—database.xlsx

EU behavioural investigations—ongoing cases tracke.PDF
EU competition law—legislation and policy tracker.PDF
General Court Digital Markets Act appeals—ongoing.PDF
UK EU Merger decisions—database.xlsx

MJ merger control—news feed.PDF
MJ merger grid—procedure.PDF
Multi-jurisdictional foreign direct investment (FD.PDF

Horiz uas.pdf
oecd(1).PDF
oecd(2).PDF
oecd(3).PDF
Oecd(4).PDF
OECD(5).PDF
oecd. Competition on the Merits.PDF
oecd.PDF
oecd. Private focs.PDF
Oecd. SLC TEST SPAIN. UK.PDF
oecd. smap evidence.pdf
UN-2_ private standards v DEVELOPING COUNTRIES.PDF
UN-6. CL AND PATENT POLICY.PDF
Vertical uas.pdf


SPAIN

Cnmc energia DPs.txt
Dec 23.Cnmc rechaza la propuesta de tv futbol retransmision.pdf
Dp energy spain.sdocx

Ec v spain. Ecj held spain in breach of radiation dir . Cocoo foc for dams 5yr tl wpi .pdf

Ec v spain. Ecj held spain in breach of radiation dir . Cocoo foc for dams 5yr tl wpi .pdf
Ec v spain. Ecj held spain in breach of radiation dir . Cocoo foc for dams 5yr tl wpi .pdf
Spain behavioural investigations—closed cases trac.PDF

ARBITRATION CASES.pdf
CLP_ALP_ RESP DE LA AP.pdf
clp __ agenda 2030.pdf
COMO ILEGALIZAR a Los zurdos e independentistas.pdf
ECJ DECISIONS V SPAIN.pdf
espana ANTICOMPS.pdf
JR & Locus. uk & spain[jca].pdf
Judge liability uk. Spain.pdf
LA MAFIA FEMINISTA. CRISTINA SEGUI.pdf
MARIO CONDE.pdf
Nextgen [hungary case] + perdon deuda a cat [malversacion] + incump de austeridad.pdf
PP_ RESP CIVIL subsidiaria, Y PENAL.pdf
REGISTRO Y FINANCIACION DE PP ESPANA.pdf
RELOJ DE PRESCRIPCION PENAL Y CIVIL.pdf
SPAIN_ EC INFRINGEMENTS.pdf
[cataluna v spain] __[nigeria v p&id ].pdf


TOP WORLD COS.BY.SECTOR:

aerospace and defence.txt
agriculture and forestry (1).txt
automotive.txt
banking (1).txt
chemical.txt
construction.txt
consultancy.txt
consumers.txt
food.txt
healthcare.txt
machinery.txt
mining.txt
oil gas .txt
packaging.txt
pharma.txt
power and utilities.txt
retail and wholesale.txt
sports.txt
tech.txt
transport . infrastructure.txt


THE UK

The_Competition_Appeal_Tribunal_Rules_2015.pdf
UK competition appeals—ongoing cases tracker.PDF


CAT.RECENT.CASES:

The_Competition_Appeal_Tribunal_Rules_2015.pdf
UK competition appeals—ongoing cases tracker.PDF

1588_Keltbray_v_CMA_Summary_of_Appeal.pdf
2023.03.08 1574 BMW AG v CMA Reasoned Order of the President (Consequentials)(Permission to Appeal).pdf
2023.03.31_1576_Apple v CMA_Judgment (FINAL).pdf
2023.06.08_1441-1444_Final Judgment (CPO Applications) [2023] CAT 38.pdf
2023.07.10_D&D_Non_Confidential_Judgment_Final.pdf
2023.07.18_1590_Ruling (Second Adjournment Application).pdf
15277722 Alex Neill Class Representative Limited v Sony Interactive Entertainment Europe Limited; Sony Interactive Entertainment Network Europe Limited; and Sony Interactive Entertainment UK Limited – Rul.pdf
15895723 (T) Infederation Ltd v Google Inc and Others – Order of the Chair (Structure Statements) 5 Sep 2023.pdf
15987723 Doug Taylor Class Representative Limited v MotoNovo Finance Limited and Others – Summary of Collective Proceedings Claim Form 24 Nov 2023.pdf
15997723 Doug Taylor Class Representative Limited v Black Horse Limited and Others – Summary of Collective Proceedings Claim Form 24 Nov 2023.pdf
16007723 Doug Taylor Class Representative Limited v Santander Consumer (UK) plc and Others – Summary of Collective Proceedings Claim Form 24 Nov 2023.pdf
16027723 Christine Riefa Class Representative Limited v Apple Inc. & Others – Reasoned Order of the Chair (Service out of the Jurisdiction) 3 Nov 2023.pdf
16027723 Christine Riefa Class Representative Limited v Apple Inc. & Others – Summary of Collective Proceedings Claim Form 28 Nov 2023.pdf
16037723 Professor Carolyn Roberts v (1) Severn Trent Water Limited and (2) Severn Trent PLC – Summary of Collective Proceedings Claim Form 14 Dec 2023.pdf
16287723 Professor Carolyn Roberts v United Utilities Water Limited (2) United Utilities Group PLC – Summary of Collective Proceedings Claim Form 2 Jan 2024.pdf
16297723 Professor Carolyn Roberts v Yorkshire Water Services Limited (2) Kelda Holdings Limited – Summary of Collective Proceedings Claim Form 2 Jan 2024.pdf
16307723 Professor Carolyn Roberts v Northumbrian Water Limited (2) Northumbrian Water Group Limited – Summary of Collective Proceedings Claim Form 2 Jan 2024.pdf
16317723 Professor Carolyn Roberts v Anglian Water Services Limited (2) Anglian Water Group Limited – Summary of Collective Proceedings Claim Form 2 Jan 2024.pdf
20230208 1574 BMW VW v CMA and 2721 R (on Application of VW AG) v CMA __ Judgment_0.pdf
157941223 Cérélia Group Holding SAS and Cérélia UK Limited v Competition and Markets Authority – Judgment 1 Sep 2023.pdf
158711223 Squibb Group Limited v Competition and Markets Authority; 158811223 – Keltbray Limited & Others v Competition and Markets Authority – Order of the Chair (Varying Directions Order) 26 Oct 2023.pdf
159361223 Airwave Solutions Limited & Others v Competition and Markets Authority – Judgment 22 Dec 2023.pdf
CICC (1441-1444) – Reasoned Order (Costs) 12 Oct 2023.pdf
CICC (1441-1444) – Reasoned Order of the Tribunal (Permission to Appeal) 2 Oct 2023.pdf
CICC (1441-1444) – Transcript of Hearing (Funding Arrangements) 10 Nov 2023.pdf
Phenytoin (1524-1525) – Transcript of case management conference 20 Sep 2023.pdf
Warrant Applications (1611-1614) – Judgment (Application for Warrants) 12 Oct 2023.pdf
Warrant Applications (1611-1614) – Order of the President 8 Dec 2023_0.pdf

 

875_0.pdf
1329,1336 O’Higgins,Evans Judgment of the Court of Appeal 09 Nov 2023.pdf
34579_1889_2.pdf
12667716 Walter Hugh Merricks CBE v Mastercard Incorporated and Others Judgment (Causation and Value of Commerce) 26 Feb 2024.pdf
13397720 Mark McLaren Class Representative Limited v MOL (Europe Africa) Ltd and Others – Court of Appeal Judgment 8 Dec 2023.pdf
14407722 Clare Mary Joan Spottiswoode CBE v Nexans France S.A.S. & Others – Judgment (Collective Proceedings Order) 3 May 2024.pdf
151711722 (UM) Merchant Interchange Fee Umbrella Proceedings – Ruling (Legal Causation) 21 Mar 2024.pdf
AT_39920_5978472_738_5.pdf
CELEX_52017XC0530(01)_EN_TXT.pdf
CELEX_52018XC0424(01)_EN_TXT.pdf


  PDFS OF SCANS:  DOWNLOAD.LINKS from g.drive


3pinting.uk.II.pdf
3pinting.uk.pdf
adr.ARB.nigeria.case.pdf
ALP.pdf
cma.investig.proc.pdf
cma.ongoing.UNDERTAKINGS.pdf
COLL.focs.sacs.pdf
competition.analysis.smartphones.I.pdf
consumer.law.pdf
contract.law.battle.of.forms.anticipat.repud.pdf
contractlaw.c.validity.pdf
contractlaw.implied.terms.IT.pdf
contractlaw.knowledge.pdf
DDREPs.how2behave.pdf
ELP.ac.pdf
ESP.BOCG.nextgen.pdf
ESP.cnmc.pdf
ESP.coadyuvante.solic.TC.pdf
ESP.csegui.pdf
ESP.dcho.danos.pdf
ESP.ico.loa.cam.pdf
ESP.locus.lba.pdf
ESP.marioconde.pdf
ESP.plusultra.csegui.pdf
ESP.proc.jcial.pdf
ESP.r.C-A.pdf
ESP.reloj.penal.pdf
eu.complaint.v.unlawful.sa.pdf
eu.DAMDIR.members.o2.comp.4.breach.eulaw.pdf
eu.ec.penalties.pdf
eu.ecj.gc.locus.innuitpeople.pdf
eu.ecj.statute.pdf
EU.jr.clp.II.pdf
EU.jr.clp.pdf
eulaw.transposition.failures.by.Members.cases.pdf
fca.LR10.pdf
FCA.pdf
fca.prebid.stake.building.pdf
foc.assignent.adr.II.pdf
foc.assignment.adr.pdf
foc.SNITCH.pdf
globalisation.wto.itas.pdf
ILP.cols.II.pdf
ILP.cols.pdf
ka.commercial.tool.pdf
ka.evaluation.tool.pdf
ka.procurement.pdf
ka.pus.o2.innov.pdf
ka.strategy.rosebook.pdf
liab.of.legal.persons.pdf
lob. -exts.pdf
lob.4.ip.oi.pdf
lob.appg.1.pdf
lob.appg.3.pdf
lob.fin.sentiment.pdf
lob.HOL.1.pdf
lob.HOL.2.pdf
lob.INVESTIGS.orcl.pdf
lob.LCOM.LCON.pdf
lob.UES.pdf
MA.highlights.ind.reps.pdf
ma.MJ.mcr.TUR.10.pdf
MATOIPO.how.2.uncover.pdf
mcr.pdf
MEDIATION.adr.pdf
miMINDS.pdf
nao.fraud&error.2024.pdf
NAO.reg.2023-24.pdf
oscar.in.da.house.II.pdf
oscar.in.da.house.pdf
PP.dissolution.pdf
PP.philosophy.pdf
prompts.clp.pdf
RD.OD.uk.pdf
RD.ratiodecidendi.pdf
RLCM.clp.cocoo.v.SPAIN.II.pdf
RLCM.p.legalidad.pdf
SETTLEMENT (1).pdf
SKELETON.ARG.pdf
STEPS.II.pdf
STEPS.pdf
strategies.clp.pdf
T.O.uk.cliffchance.pdf
uk.PUS.liab.pdf
USP: cocoo.o2.usp.ec.pdf
USPS.ccs.uk.pdf
USPS.global.I.pdf
USPS.ipr.ka.pdf
USPS.ipr.national.invisible.wealth.III.pdf
USPS.lvps.pdf
USPS.nic.uk.pdf
USPS.ppp.framework.uk.pdf
USPS.ppp.rh.TAP.pdf
USPS.ppp.roadshighways.pdf
USPS.PPPS.pdf
USPS.proc.exemption.cliff.chance.pdf
USPS.uk.rail.dft.mcps.pdf
valuation.intrinsic.analysis.pdf
VALUATIONS.5+6.I.pdf
valuations:finstat.value.manip.pdf


 

3PINTING.clp.pdf
3PINTING.cma.investigs.pdf
3pints.how2join.cma.investigs.pdf
adr.novat.assignm.collfoc.II.pdf
adr.novat.assignm.collfoc.pdf
cat.claims.jr.nojr-II.pdf
cat.claims.jr.nojr.pdf
CAT.pdf
competition.analysis.tools.pdf
contractlaw.c.challenge.pdf
contractlaw.c.formation.pdf
contractlaw.loopholes.pdf
contractlaw.QLTT.pdf
Error.prefs.6-I.pdf
Error.prefs.6-II.pdf
ESP.cnmc.pdf
ESP.cocons.pdf
ESP.lohp.pdf
ESP.pp.financiacion.pdf
eu.DAM.DIR.pdf
eu.DAMDIR.members.o2.comp.4.breach.eulaw.II.pdf
eu.EC.made.realma.pdf
eulaw.preambles.citations.pdf
FOC.arbitration.pdf
FTM.pdf
funding.sources.pdf
ILP.od.ar.pdf
IPOS.pdf
ka.types.rosebook.pdf
L+.pdf
lob.appg.2.pdf
lob.appg.4.pdf
lob.disc.rates.pdf
lob.eu.pdf
lob.GOVGROUPS.pdf
lob.SIS.uk.pdf
lob.UK.USA.pdf
ma.BA.uk.pdf
MAD.MAS.challenge.KAPLOV. 1+ 5.pdf
madmas.kaplov.pdf
MATOIPO.biws.pples.pdf
mcr.cliff.chance.pdf
OC.OS.APPs.pdf
oscar.CBI.FSI.member.orgs.pdf
petitions.eumember.parlms.pdf

PETITION.FILING.change.org

PSDR.pdf
RD.radiodecidendi.II.pdf
RLCM.clp.cocoo.v.SPAIN.pdf
SETTLEMENT.pdf
stealthcons.pdf
strategy.clp.map.pdf
STRATEGY.toolbook.pdf
SUBSlaw.PROClaw.pdf
SUSTUAS.challenges. HOW2quantum.clp.harm CMA.investigs my2approaches DDRs.pdf
T.O.faqs.pdf
tax.avoidance.ELON.pdf
uk.CPR.5.45.pdf
uk.HC.COMCO.pdf
uk.SC.pdf
USPS.2.cma.pdf
USPS.3P.riskmitig.creditenhance.pdf
USPS.aus.pdf
USPS.ipa.uk.pdf
USPS.ipr.clp.pdf
USPS.ipr.national.invisible.wealth.II.pdf
USPS.ipr.national.invisible.wealth.pdf
USPS.ipr.uk.pdf
USPS.ita=ipr.valuation.pdf
USPS.mackreport.uk.pdf
USPS.nda.pdf
USPS.pdf
USPS.ppp.RISKS.pdf
USPS.ppp.roadhigw.revenues.pdf
USPS.ppp.roadshighw.PUBL.CONSULTATION.pdf
USPS.pus.Bal.Sheet.review.pdf
USPS.PUS.o2.consider.ppp.options.pdf
VALUATIONS.5+6.II.pdf
VALUATIONS.5+6.III.pdf


 

Posted by wpMY0dxsz043 in COCOO CASES, 0 comments

complaint.v.eu.AGENCIES

1. List of Perpetrators and Victims:

Perpetrators:

  • European Union Agency for Asylum (EUAA): Alleged maladministration in handling asylum procedures.
  • European Union Intellectual Property Office (EUIPO): Alleged unfair practices in trademark registrations.
  • European Medicines Agency (EMA): Alleged delays in the approval of generic medicines.

Victims and Estimated Compensation:

  • Asylum Seekers: Suffered due to procedural inefficiencies.
    • Estimated Compensation: €5,000 per individual.
  • Small and Medium Enterprises (SMEs): Faced obstacles in trademark registrations.
    • Estimated Compensation: €10,000 per SME.
  • Generic Pharmaceutical Companies: Incurred losses due to approval delays.
    • Estimated Compensation: €15,000 per company.

2. Draft Letters of Complaint:

a. Complaint Against the European Union Agency for Asylum (EUAA):

[Your Name]
[Your Position]
COCOO
[Your Address]
[City, Postal Code]
[Email Address]
[Date]

Subject: Formal Complaint Regarding Procedural Inefficiencies at the European Union Agency for Asylum (EUAA)

To Whom It May Concern,

I am writing on behalf of COCOO to formally lodge a complaint concerning procedural inefficiencies within the EUAA that have adversely affected asylum seekers. Our investigation has identified significant delays and administrative hurdles that compromise the rights and well-being of individuals seeking asylum within the European Union.

Details of the Complaint:

  • Nature of the Issue: Excessive delays in processing asylum applications, leading to prolonged uncertainty and hardship for applicants.
  • Affected Parties: Asylum seekers across various EU member states.
  • Evidence: Documented cases of applicants experiencing processing times exceeding the stipulated legal framework, resulting in psychological distress and financial instability.

Requested Action:

We urge the EUAA to:

  1. Conduct a comprehensive review of current procedures to identify and rectify inefficiencies.
  2. Implement measures to ensure timely processing of asylum applications in compliance with EU regulations.
  3. Provide compensation of €5,000 to each affected asylum seeker for the undue hardship caused by these delays.

We anticipate your prompt attention to this matter and a response outlining the steps the EUAA intends to take to address these concerns.

Sincerely,

[Your Name]
[Your Position]
COCOO

b. Complaint Against the European Union Intellectual Property Office (EUIPO):

[Your Name]
[Your Position]
COCOO
[Your Address]
[City, Postal Code]
[Email Address]
[Date]

Subject: Formal Complaint Regarding Unfair Trademark Registration Practices at the European Union Intellectual Property Office (EUIPO)

To Whom It May Concern,

On behalf of COCOO, I am submitting a formal complaint concerning unfair practices in the trademark registration process at the EUIPO, which have disproportionately affected Small and Medium Enterprises (SMEs).

Details of the Complaint:

  • Nature of the Issue: Discriminatory practices favoring larger corporations over SMEs in trademark registration, including expedited processing and reduced scrutiny for larger applicants.
  • Affected Parties: SMEs seeking trademark registrations within the EU.
  • Evidence: Instances where SME applications have faced unwarranted delays and rejections, while similar applications from larger entities have been approved promptly.

Requested Action:

We request that the EUIPO:

  1. Investigate and eliminate any discriminatory practices within the trademark registration process.
  2. Ensure equal treatment and transparency for all applicants, regardless of their size.
  3. Compensate each affected SME with €10,000 for the financial losses incurred due to these unfair practices.

We look forward to your immediate action to rectify these issues and to a response detailing the measures to be implemented.

Sincerely,

[Your Name]
[Your Position]
COCOO

c. Complaint Against the European Medicines Agency (EMA):

[Your Name]
[Your Position]
COCOO
[Your Address]
[City, Postal Code]
[Email Address]
[Date]

Subject: Formal Complaint Regarding Delays in Approval of Generic Medicines by the European Medicines Agency (EMA)

To Whom It May Concern,

COCOO hereby submits a formal complaint regarding undue delays by the EMA in approving generic medicines, adversely impacting generic pharmaceutical companies and public health.

Details of the Complaint:

  • Nature of the Issue: Protracted approval processes for generic medicines, delaying market entry and limiting access to affordable medication.
  • Affected Parties: Generic pharmaceutical companies and consumers within the EU.
  • Evidence: Cases where generic drug approvals have exceeded standard timelines without valid justification, resulting in financial losses for companies and continued high costs for consumers.

Requested Action:

We urge the EMA to:

  1. Review and streamline the approval process for generic medicines to prevent unnecessary delays.
  2. Establish clear timelines and accountability measures to ensure adherence to approval schedules.
  3. Compensate each affected generic pharmaceutical company with €15,000 for losses incurred due to these delays.

We expect prompt corrective actions and a detailed response outlining the steps the EMA will take to address these concerns.

Sincerely,

[Your Name]
[Your Position]
COCOO

3. Summary of Compensation:

  • Asylum Seekers: €5,000 per individual.
  • SMEs: €10,000 per company.
  • Generic Pharmaceutical Companies: €15,000 per company.

Note: The above compensation amounts are estimates. Actual figures should be determined based on detailed assessments of individual cases.

These letters are intended to formally notify the respective agencies of the identified issues and to seek appropriate remedies on behalf of the affected parties.

Sources

4o

 

 


perplexity

Based on the information provided in the search results, here is a breakdown of the cases with victims and estimated damages:

  1. Irregular Payments by ELA
    Victims and Damages:
  • Competitors (e.g., Contractor A, Contractor B): €5 million
  • Excluded Contractors (e.g., Contractor C, Contractor D): €3 million
    Total Estimated Damages: €8 million
  1. Contract Splitting by CPVO
    Victims and Damages:
  • Excluded Suppliers (e.g., Supplier X, Supplier Y): €2 million
  • Administrative Inefficiencies: €1.5 million
    Total Estimated Damages: €3.5 million
  1. Transparency Issues by SRB
    Victims and Damages:
  • Excluded Financial Institutions (e.g., Bank A, Bank B): €10 million
  • Loss of Public Trust (impacting consumers and stakeholders): €5 million
    Total Estimated Damages: €15 million
  1. Financial Checks Mismanagement by EEA
    Victims and Damages:
  • Excluded Competitors (e.g., Grant Applicant X, Grant Applicant Y): €4 million
  • Misallocated EU Funds: €2 million
    Total Estimated Damages: €6 million

These breakdowns provide an estimate of the damages for each case, identifying specific victim types and the corresponding amounts to be claimed

 

 


Audit Reports: The European Court of Auditors publishes annual reports that may include findings related to the EEA. For instance, the 2021 Audit of EU agencies provides insights into various agencies’ operations, including the EEA.European Court of Auditors


i ask:

Competition Law and Policy Insights

1. Irregular Payments by ELA

  • Competition Law Issues:
    • Irregular payments undermine the principles of fair competition by favoring certain suppliers over others. This distorts market access and creates an unequal playing field for potential contractors, violating Article 101 TFEU (anti-competitive agreements) and potentially Article 102 TFEU (abuse of dominant position if a favored supplier becomes dominant due to preferential treatment).
  • New Grounds for Complaint:
    • Breach of fair competition through discriminatory procurement practices.
    • Potential collusion between ELA officials and specific contractors, violating competition rules.
  • Estimated Damages Breakdown:
    • Competitors (e.g., Contractor A, Contractor B): €5 million.
    • Excluded Contractors (e.g., Contractor C, Contractor D): €3 million.
    • Total Estimated Damages: €8 million.

2. Contract Splitting by CPVO

  • Competition Law Issues:
    • Splitting contracts to avoid tendering requirements prevents open and fair competition, contravening EU public procurement rules. This limits market access for other potential suppliers, harming competition and efficiency.
  • New Grounds for Complaint:
    • Artificial division of contracts to circumvent competitive tendering.
    • Restriction of competition by preventing other suppliers from participating in the bidding process.
  • Estimated Damages Breakdown:
    • Excluded Suppliers (e.g., Supplier X, Supplier Y): €2 million.
    • Administrative Inefficiencies: €1.5 million.
    • Total Estimated Damages: €3.5 million.

3. Transparency Issues by SRB

  • Competition Law Issues:
    • Lack of transparency in financial and budgetary operations creates uncertainty in the banking and financial services market. This undermines trust and potentially skews competition by favoring certain financial institutions with better insider knowledge.
  • New Grounds for Complaint:
    • Failure to provide a level playing field in the financial sector due to non-transparent regulatory practices.
    • Unfair advantage given to certain financial institutions, harming competitors and the broader public interest.
  • Estimated Damages Breakdown:
    • Excluded Financial Institutions (e.g., Bank A, Bank B): €10 million.
    • Loss of Public Trust (impacting consumers and stakeholders): €5 million.
    • Total Estimated Damages: €15 million.

4. Financial Checks Mismanagement by EEA

  • Competition Law Issues:
    • Mismanagement of financial checks creates inefficiencies and risks in awarding grants and contracts. This can lead to the exclusion of more qualified competitors, distorting competition and undermining market efficiency.
  • New Grounds for Complaint:
    • Disruption of fair competition in grant allocation and contract awards.
    • Inefficient use of EU funds, harming the public interest and excluding better-qualified competitors.
  • Estimated Damages Breakdown:
    • Excluded Competitors (e.g., Grant Applicant X, Grant Applicant Y): €4 million.
    • Misallocated EU Funds: €2 million.
    • Total Estimated Damages: €6 million.

Draft Letter of Claim for Damages

[Your Address]
[Date]
[Recipient’s Address]

Subject: Notice of Claim for Damages

Dear [Recipient],

We act on behalf of COCOO, an organization committed to enforcing competition law within the EU. We hereby submit this claim for damages under Article 340 TFEU against [Agency Name] for breaches of EU competition law and public procurement rules, which have caused harm to the public interest, competitors, suppliers, and consumers. Below, we outline the specific grounds for each claim:

1. Claim Against the European Labour Authority (ELA)

  • Grounds:
    • Irregular payments violating procurement rules.
    • Discrimination against competing suppliers, distorting market competition.
    • Breach of Articles 101 and 102 TFEU through favoritism and anti-competitive practices.
  • Damages Claimed: €8 million.

2. Claim Against the Community Plant Variety Office (CPVO)

  • Grounds:
    • Splitting of contracts to avoid tendering requirements, restricting fair competition.
    • Violation of EU public procurement regulations and Articles 49 and 56 TFEU (freedom of establishment and services).
  • Damages Claimed: €3.5 million.

3. Claim Against the Single Resolution Board (SRB)

  • Grounds:
    • Lack of transparency in financial management, distorting competition in the financial sector.
    • Unfair regulatory practices giving undue advantages to certain financial institutions.
  • Damages Claimed: €15 million.

4. Claim Against the European Environment Agency (EEA)

  • Grounds:
    • Mismanagement of financial checks, leading to inefficiencies and exclusion of qualified competitors.
    • Breach of EU financial and procurement regulations, undermining fair competition.
  • Damages Claimed: €6 million.

Conclusion

We urge you to address this matter promptly and compensate for the damages incurred due to your agency’s actions. Failure to resolve this claim within [set deadline, e.g., 30 days] will compel us to escalate the matter to the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU).

Yours faithfully,
[Your Name]
Competition Lawyer
COCOO

 

 


You said:

i dont seeit. how can we returntothe previous style of chatting?
ChatGPT said:
ChatGPT

To return to the previous chat style, simply close the document view or let me know, and I’ll switch back to regular chat. Let me know how I can assist further!

 

You said:
dont give me the document as a link , but paste it as text
ChatGPT said:
ChatGPT

Understood! Here’s the full content pasted as text:


Competition Law and Policy Insights

1. Irregular Payments by ELA

  • Competition Law Issues:
    • Irregular payments undermine the principles of fair competition by favoring certain suppliers over others. This distorts market access and creates an unequal playing field for potential contractors, violating Article 101 TFEU (anti-competitive agreements) and potentially Article 102 TFEU (abuse of dominant position if a favored supplier becomes dominant due to preferential treatment).
  • New Grounds for Complaint:
    • Breach of fair competition through discriminatory procurement practices.
    • Potential collusion between ELA officials and specific contractors, violating competition rules.
  • Estimated Damages Breakdown:
    • Competitors (e.g., Contractor A, Contractor B): €5 million.
    • Excluded Contractors (e.g., Contractor C, Contractor D): €3 million.
    • Total Estimated Damages: €8 million.

2. Contract Splitting by CPVO

  • Competition Law Issues:
    • Splitting contracts to avoid tendering requirements prevents open and fair competition, contravening EU public procurement rules. This limits market access for other potential suppliers, harming competition and efficiency.
  • New Grounds for Complaint:
    • Artificial division of contracts to circumvent competitive tendering.
    • Restriction of competition by preventing other suppliers from participating in the bidding process.
  • Estimated Damages Breakdown:
    • Excluded Suppliers (e.g., Supplier X, Supplier Y): €2 million.
    • Administrative Inefficiencies: €1.5 million.
    • Total Estimated Damages: €3.5 million.

3. Transparency Issues by SRB

  • Competition Law Issues:
    • Lack of transparency in financial and budgetary operations creates uncertainty in the banking and financial services market. This undermines trust and potentially skews competition by favoring certain financial institutions with better insider knowledge.
  • New Grounds for Complaint:
    • Failure to provide a level playing field in the financial sector due to non-transparent regulatory practices.
    • Unfair advantage given to certain financial institutions, harming competitors and the broader public interest.
  • Estimated Damages Breakdown:
    • Excluded Financial Institutions (e.g., Bank A, Bank B): €10 million.
    • Loss of Public Trust (impacting consumers and stakeholders): €5 million.
    • Total Estimated Damages: €15 million.

4. Financial Checks Mismanagement by EEA

  • Competition Law Issues:
    • Mismanagement of financial checks creates inefficiencies and risks in awarding grants and contracts. This can lead to the exclusion of more qualified competitors, distorting competition and undermining market efficiency.
  • New Grounds for Complaint:
    • Disruption of fair competition in grant allocation and contract awards.
    • Inefficient use of EU funds, harming the public interest and excluding better-qualified competitors.
  • Estimated Damages Breakdown:
    • Excluded Competitors (e.g., Grant Applicant X, Grant Applicant Y): €4 million.
    • Misallocated EU Funds: €2 million.
    • Total Estimated Damages: €6 million.

Draft Letter of Claim for Damages

[Your Address]
[Date]
[Recipient’s Address]

Subject: Notice of Claim for Damages

Dear [Recipient],

We act on behalf of COCOO, an organization committed to enforcing competition law within the EU. We hereby submit this claim for damages under Article 340 TFEU against [Agency Name] for breaches of EU competition law and public procurement rules, which have caused harm to the public interest, competitors, suppliers, and consumers. Below, we outline the specific grounds for each claim:

1. Claim Against the European Labour Authority (ELA)

  • Grounds:
    • Irregular payments violating procurement rules.
    • Discrimination against competing suppliers, distorting market competition.
    • Breach of Articles 101 and 102 TFEU through favoritism and anti-competitive practices.
  • Damages Claimed: €8 million.

2. Claim Against the Community Plant Variety Office (CPVO)

  • Grounds:
    • Splitting of contracts to avoid tendering requirements, restricting fair competition.
    • Violation of EU public procurement regulations and Articles 49 and 56 TFEU (freedom of establishment and services).
  • Damages Claimed: €3.5 million.

3. Claim Against the Single Resolution Board (SRB)

  • Grounds:
    • Lack of transparency in financial management, distorting competition in the financial sector.
    • Unfair regulatory practices giving undue advantages to certain financial institutions.
  • Damages Claimed: €15 million.

4. Claim Against the European Environment Agency (EEA)

  • Grounds:
    • Mismanagement of financial checks, leading to inefficiencies and exclusion of qualified competitors.
    • Breach of EU financial and procurement regulations, undermining fair competition.
  • Damages Claimed: €6 million.

Conclusion

We urge you to address this matter promptly and compensate for the damages incurred due to your agency’s actions. Failure to resolve this claim within [set deadline, e.g., 30 days] will compel us to escalate the matter to the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU).

Yours faithfully,
[Your Name]
Competition Lawyer
COCOO


You said:
give me a list of the main perpetrators, whether public institutions, or private or public companies etc
ChatGPT said:
ChatGPT

Here is a list of the main perpetrators identified in each case:


1. Irregular Payments by ELA

  • Perpetrator:
    • European Labour Authority (ELA) (Public Institution)

2. Contract Splitting by CPVO

  • Perpetrator:
    • Community Plant Variety Office (CPVO) (Public Institution)

3. Transparency Issues by SRB

  • Perpetrator:
    • Single Resolution Board (SRB) (Public Institution)

4. Financial Checks Mismanagement by EEA

  • Perpetrator:
    • European Environment Agency (EEA) (Public Institution)

These perpetrators are all public institutions operating under the EU framework. Let me know if you need further clarification or detailed information about each

You said:
how many damages claims on these matters, have , to date, been filed?
ChatGPT said:
ChatGPT

As of now, there is no publicly available information indicating that any damages claims have been filed against the European Labour Authority (ELA), Community Plant Variety Office (CPVO), Single Resolution Board (SRB), or European Environment Agency (EEA) concerning the specific issues you’ve mentioned. While there have been general discussions and legal clarifications regarding damages claims within the European Economic Area (EEA)

, no specific claims against these agencies have been reported. It’s important to note that the absence of publicly available information does not necessarily mean that no claims have been filed; some claims may not be publicly disclosed due to confidentiality or ongoing legal proceedings.

As of now, there is no publicly available information indicating that arbitration proceedings have been initiated concerning the specific issues involving the European Labour Authority (ELA), Community Plant Variety Office (CPVO), Single Resolution Board (SRB), or European Environment Agency (EEA) that you’ve mentioned. While arbitration is a common method for resolving disputes in various sectors, there are no records of such proceedings related to these matters. It’s important to note that arbitration proceedings are often confidential, and the absence of publicly available information does not necessarily mean that no proceedings have occurred. However, based on the accessible data, no arbitration cases have been reported in these instances.

You said:
you are an expert competition lawyer. why do you think that the victims have not claimed?, why nobody claimed for damages or for review, of the decisions that have led to the loss of so much money? could it be that , because this is european taxpayer money, and individual taxpayers lack locus or eligibility to claim on behalf of all taxpayers? would therefore, these cases be ideal for the cocoo to take over in pro of the public interest and consumers?
ChatGPT said:
ChatGPT

Your analysis touches on several critical issues. Here’s why I believe no claims have been filed and why these cases may present an opportunity for COCOO to intervene:


Reasons for Lack of Claims

  1. Lack of Direct Locus Standi for Individual Taxpayers:
    • European Taxpayer Money: Individual taxpayers typically cannot claim damages or challenge decisions that affect the general EU budget because they lack a direct and specific legal interest (locus standi). The harm is diffuse and impacts the broader public rather than individuals directly.
  2. Complexity and High Legal Barriers:
    • Procedural Barriers: Claiming damages or seeking judicial review of decisions involving EU agencies requires navigating complex legal procedures, which can deter potential claimants.
    • Financial and Expertise Costs: Litigation against powerful institutions like the SRB, CPVO, or EEA can be expensive, requiring resources and expertise beyond the reach of most individuals or small organizations.
  3. Lack of Awareness or Coordination:
    • Low Public Awareness: Many victims (e.g., excluded suppliers or contractors) may not realize their rights have been violated or lack the resources to pursue claims.
    • Absence of Coordinated Action: The diffuse nature of the harm makes it difficult to organize collective legal action, unlike in cases of direct consumer harm.
  4. Confidentiality and Limited Transparency:
    • Opaque Processes: Decisions involving procurement or financial management are often shrouded in bureaucracy, making it hard for potential claimants to gather the necessary evidence to build a case.

Suitability for COCOO to Take Action

  1. COCOO’s Mandate to Protect Public Interest:
    • As an organization dedicated to enforcing competition law and ensuring fairness, COCOO is ideally positioned to step in where individual taxpayers or victims cannot.
    • COCOO can argue that these breaches undermine the principles of transparency, accountability, and competition that EU institutions are bound to uphold.
  2. Standing to Represent Collective Interests:
    • Public Interest: COCOO could claim standing to act on behalf of European taxpayers, consumers, and excluded competitors by demonstrating the broader societal harm caused by these breaches.
    • Advocacy for Consumers and Suppliers: COCOO can represent excluded suppliers, contractors, or competitors who lack the resources or knowledge to pursue their claims.
  3. Strategic Litigation to Set Precedents:
    • Filing claims or seeking judicial review would not only address the specific breaches but also send a strong signal to EU agencies about the need for stricter compliance with competition and procurement rules.
    • Successful cases could establish legal precedents, strengthening future enforcement and oversight.
  4. Potential for Policy Change:
    • By taking legal action, COCOO could push for reforms in EU agencies’ decision-making and procurement processes, ensuring greater transparency and accountability.

Conclusion

The lack of individual claims highlights a gap in enforcement that COCOO is well-placed to fill. These cases represent an opportunity for COCOO to step in, acting in the public interest and on behalf of consumers and excluded competitors. By doing so, COCOO could ensure that EU agencies are held accountable for breaches that undermine competition and waste taxpayer money. Let me know if you’d like to outline a legal strategy or draft a detailed action plan.

 

Posted by wpMY0dxsz043 in COCOO CASES, 0 comments

ECA.24: all possible complaints

You said:
go online and give me the email address and links to relevant claim for damages, and complaint forms that we need to complete….except those where the limitation period to claim or complaint has passed. today is 13 january 2025

Based on the current date, January 13, 2025, and the information provided, here are the relevant contact details and resources for filing complaints and claims where the limitation periods have not expired:

1. Meta Platforms Inc. (Abuse of Dominance in Data Processing)

  • Damages Claim:
    • Procedure: In the EU, damages claims for competition law infringements are pursued through national courts. Each Member State has its own procedures and forms.
    • Guidance: The European Commission provides general information on actions for damages under EU competition rules.
  • Complaint to the European Commission:

2. České dráhy a.s. (Abuse of Dominance in Rail Transport)

  • Damages Claim:
    • Procedure: As with other EU Member States, damages claims are handled by national courts. Consult the relevant national competition authority or legal counsel for specific procedures.
    • Guidance: Refer to the European Commission’s page on actions for damages for general information.
  • Complaint to the European Commission:

3. Unilever Italia (Exclusivity Clauses in Distribution)

4. Valve Corporation (Geoblocking Case)

  • Damages Claim:
    • Procedure: Pursue claims through national courts in the relevant Member State. Seek legal advice for specific procedures.
    • Guidance: General information is available on the European Commission’s actions for damages page.
  • Complaint to the European Commission:

Note: While the European Commission provides general guidance, the actual filing of damages claims is conducted through national legal systems. It’s advisable to consult with legal professionals experienced in competition law within the relevant jurisdictions to ensure compliance with specific procedures and deadlines.

For more detailed information on the process and your rights, you can refer to the European Commission’s page on actions for damages.

Additionally, the European Law Institute has published a statement on collective redress and competition damages claims, which may provide further insights.

If you wish to report a breach of EU law by an EU country, the European Commission provides guidance on how to proceed.

For general complaints about breaches of EU law by Member States, you can use the complaint form provided by the European Commission.


You said:
what are the email contact address or web link contact form, for the lawyers representing those companies and organisations?:

Based on the available information, here are the contact details for the legal representatives of the specified companies:

1. Meta Platforms Inc. (formerly Facebook Inc.)

  • Legal Counsel:
    • In-House Legal Team:
      • Chief Legal Officer: Jennifer G. Newstead, J.D.
      • Chief Compliance Officer: Henry T. A. Moniz
    • External Legal Representation:

2. Valve Corporation

  • Legal Counsel:
    • In-House Legal Team:
      • General Counsel: Not publicly disclosed
    • External Legal Representation:

3. Unilever Italia

  • Legal Counsel:
    • In-House Legal Team:
      • General Counsel: Not publicly disclosed
    • External Legal Representation:

4. České dráhy a.s. (Czech Railways)

  • Legal Counsel:
    • In-House Legal Team:
      • General Counsel: Not publicly disclosed
    • External Legal Representation:

Note: Specific contact information for in-house legal teams is often not publicly available. For external legal representatives, reaching out via the provided law firm websites is recommended. Please be aware that contacting these firms does not guarantee a response, as they represent the interests of their clients. For formal legal communications, it’s advisable to consult with your own legal counsel to ensure proper protocol is followed.


what are the email address or contact web links, for the companies or individuals or organisations that have been harmed, our could have been harmed ?

Identifying specific companies or individuals harmed by the antitrust violations of entities like Meta Platforms Inc. and Valve Corporation can be challenging due to confidentiality and the broad impact of such practices. However, based on available information, here are some potential contacts:

1. Meta Platforms Inc. (Abuse of Dominance in Data Processing)

Meta was fined €797.72 million by the European Commission for antitrust violations related to Facebook Marketplace.

2. Valve Corporation (Geoblocking Practices)

Valve and five publishers were fined €7.8 million by the European Commission for geo-blocking practices affecting PC video games.

  • Potentially Harmed Parties:
    • Consumers in Affected Regions:
      • Consumer Protection Organizations:
        • European Consumer Organisation (BEUC):

Legal Basis for Claims Against NCAs:

  1. Failure to Enforce Competition Law (Article 102 TFEU):NCAs are obligated to ensure effective competition under EU and national competition laws. If an NCA failed to investigate or take enforcement action against clear infringements (e.g., abuse of dominance, cartels), a complaint may be warranted.
  2. Failure to Act (Article 265 TFEU):A claim can be brought before the General Court if an NCA or the European Commission fails to act where they are legally required to intervene.
  3. Procedural Errors or Rights Violations:NCAs must follow due process when investigating competition cases. Failure to comply with procedural rules (e.g., deadlines, right to be heard) could form the basis of a judicial review.
  4. Judicial Review of Decisions:Decisions by NCAs (e.g., rejecting complaints, imposing insufficient fines) can be challenged before national courts or EU courts if they fail to comply with EU law or lack sufficient reasoning.

Factors Affecting the Prospects of Success:

  1. Case Precedents: Cases such as RegioJet (C-57/21) and Lietuvos Geležinkeliai (C-42/21) highlight instances where claimants have successfully argued that NCAs or the European Commission failed to address anticompetitive conduct adequately.
  2. Public Interest Harm: Demonstrating significant harm to consumers, competitors, or the internal market increases the likelihood of success, as enforcement agencies are expected to prioritize cases with widespread impact


As the legal representative of COCOO, an organization dedicated to enforcing competition law, I have reviewed the provided information and conducted further research to identify potential avenues for complaints and claims. Below is a comprehensive analysis:

1. Potential Complaints and Claims:

a. European Union Agency for the Space Programme (EUSPA):

  • Grounds for Complaint: Allegations of anti-competitive procurement practices, including favoritism towards certain contractors and lack of transparency in tender processes.
  • Supporting Evidence: Audit reports indicating irregularities in procurement procedures, testimonies from excluded bidders, and discrepancies in contract awards.
  • Forum for Complaint: European Commission’s Directorate-General for Competition (DG COMP).
  • Type of Harm: Distortion of fair competition, leading to market inefficiencies.
  • Date Harm Started: Specific instances to be determined based on audit findings.
  • Time Limit for Complaint: Complaints to the European Commission should be lodged within a reasonable time frame upon discovering the infringement.
  • Perpetrator: EUSPA.
  • Victims: Competing contractors, public interest, and consumers indirectly affected by reduced innovation and higher costs.

b. Community Plant Variety Office (CPVO):

  • Grounds for Complaint: Potential anti-competitive behavior in the granting of plant variety rights, possibly favoring certain applicants.
  • Supporting Evidence: Case law indicating challenges to CPVO decisions, patterns of approvals favoring specific entities.
  • Forum for Complaint: European Court of Justice (ECJ) for judicial review; European Ombudsman for maladministration complaints.
  • Type of Harm: Unfair market advantages, hindering competition.
  • Date Harm Started: To be determined based on specific cases.
  • Time Limit for Complaint: Judicial review typically within two months of the decision; complaints to the Ombudsman within two years of the incident.
  • Perpetrator: CPVO.
  • Victims: Disadvantaged plant breeders, consumers facing limited choices.

c. Single Resolution Board (SRB):

  • Grounds for Complaint: Allegations of anti-competitive decisions in bank resolutions, potentially favoring certain financial institutions.
  • Supporting Evidence: Audit reports, market analyses showing preferential treatment.
  • Forum for Complaint: European Court of Justice (ECJ) for judicial review.
  • Type of Harm: Market distortion in the banking sector.
  • Date Harm Started: To be determined based on specific resolutions.
  • Time Limit for Complaint: Judicial review typically within two months of the decision.
  • Perpetrator: SRB.
  • Victims: Competing banks, public interest due to financial instability.

d. European Environment Agency (EEA):

  • Grounds for Complaint: Potential anti-competitive practices in awarding research contracts, possibly limiting market access for certain firms.
  • Supporting Evidence: Audit findings, complaints from excluded contractors.
  • Forum for Complaint: European Commission’s Directorate-General for Competition (DG COMP).
  • Type of Harm: Restriction of competition in environmental research.
  • Date Harm Started: To be determined based on specific contract awards.
  • Time Limit for Complaint: Complaints should be lodged within a reasonable time frame upon discovering the infringement.
  • Perpetrator: EEA.
  • Victims: Excluded research firms, public interest due to potential suppression of environmental innovations.

2. Analysis of Time Limits for Claims:

  • EUSPA: Assuming the latest audit report was published on 1st January 2024, complaints should be filed by 1st January 2025.
  • CPVO: If a contentious decision was made on 1st December 2024, judicial review should be sought by 1st February 2025.
  • SRB: For a resolution decision dated 15th November 2024, judicial review should be filed by 15th January 2025.
  • EEA: If procurement irregularities were discovered on 1st October 2024, complaints should be lodged by 1st October 2025.

3. Potential Reasons for Lack of Claims:

  • Lack of Awareness: Victims may be unaware of their rights or the infringement.
  • Resource Constraints: High legal costs and complexity deter claims.
  • Standing Issues: Individual taxpayers may lack locus standi to claim on behalf of all taxpayers.
  • Fear of Retaliation: Businesses may fear repercussions from powerful entities.

4. Role of COCOO:

COCOO can act in the public interest to address these infringements by:

  • Filing Complaints: Lodging complaints with appropriate forums.
  • Raising Awareness: Informing potential victims of their rights.
  • Advocacy: Pushing for policy changes to prevent future infringements.

5. Estimated Quantum of Damages:

Precise quantification requires detailed economic analysis. However, based on the nature of the infringements, damages could range from millions to potentially billions of euros, considering the scale of EU operations and budgets.

6. Draft Letters of Claim:

Sample Letter for EUSPA:

[Your Name]
[Your Position]
COCOO
[Address]
[Email

Sources

 


you are the lawyer of the cocoo, an organisation that enforces competition law. read the attachment in depth, looking for points of law and points of fact, and insights into actual or potential competition violations. what companies or organisations (example, the eu commission) can we file a complaint about?. For example, the the commission fail to enforce competition law, by tacking any potential competition violations?. Who was harmed as a result?: the public interest, consumers, competitors? what were the harms? any negative externalities?. before you give an answer, go online and browse for relevant information: legal precedents, news, insights, etc to strengthen our legal position and evidence…. GIVE ME A FULL LIST OF COMPANIES AND ORGANISATIONS THAT HARM COMPETITION LAW. WE MUST COMPLAIN ABOUT THEM. WHAT HARMS WERE INFLICTED? ARE THE HARMS ONGOING? NAME THE PERPETRATORS OF THOSE HARMS TO COMPETITION LAW, CONSUMER LAW, AND PUBLIC INTEREST:


CHATGPT:

Based on the thorough review of the uploaded materials and additional legal precedents, here is a detailed list of companies and organizations that have harmed competition law, consumer interests, or the public interest, along with specific harms inflicted:

1. European Commission (State Aid Control)

  • Complaint Basis: The Commission demonstrated shortcomings in monitoring crisis-related state aid, notably during the COVID-19 pandemic and the Russian invasion of Ukraine. These deficiencies created inconsistencies and potentially skewed the competitive landscape within the EU.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Distorted Competition: Insufficient oversight allowed state aid to favor certain companies without proper checks​.
    • Public Interest Impact: The failure to evaluate competition effects weakened public trust in fair competition policies.

2. Meta Platforms Inc. (formerly Facebook)

  • Complaint Basis: Abuse of a dominant position in social networking by processing user data under terms inconsistent with GDPR. Meta was found to impose unfair conditions on users and leverage data practices to suppress competition​.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Consumer Exploitation: Users had limited control over their data.
    • Competitor Exclusion: Smaller social networks faced significant barriers to entry.

3. České dráhy a.s. (Czech Railways)

  • Complaint Basis: Accused of abusing its dominant position in the rail sector by impeding competition from private operators such as RegioJet​.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Restricted Market Entry: New entrants faced discriminatory practices.
    • Consumer Harm: Limited options for passengers and potentially higher fares.

4. Daimler AG (Trucks Cartel)

  • Complaint Basis: Participation in collusive pricing agreements in violation of Article 101 TFEU​.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Overpricing: Consumers and businesses overpaid for trucks.
    • Distorted Market Dynamics: Stifled competition among truck manufacturers.

5. Lietuvos Geležinkeliai (Lithuanian Railways)

  • Complaint Basis: Removed a key railway section to exclude competitors from accessing the freight market, violating Article 102 TFEU​.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Competitor Exclusion: Orlen Lietuva, a key competitor, suffered operational disruptions.
    • Public Interest: Inefficiencies in the rail network and reduced market competition.

6. Unilever Italia

  • Complaint Basis: Abuse of dominance through exclusivity clauses in distribution agreements​.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Market Foreclosure: Retailers were tied to Unilever products.
    • Reduced Consumer Choice: Limited availability of rival products.

7. Bulgarian Energy Holding (BEH) Group

  • Complaint Basis: Refusal to grant access to gas infrastructure, breaching Article 102 TFEU​.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Restricted Market Access: Other suppliers faced entry barriers.
    • Consumer Costs: Higher energy prices due to reduced competition.

8. Google (Google Shopping Case)

  • Complaint Basis: Self-preferencing its own comparison shopping service over competitors on its general search platform, violating Article 102 TFEU​.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Competitor Suppression: Rival shopping services lost visibility.
    • Consumer Harm: Reduced access to competitive prices and services.

9. Valve Corporation (Geoblocking Case)

  • Complaint Basis: Restricting cross-border sales of video games through geoblocking, limiting market integration​.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Consumer Exploitation: Denied consumers the benefits of cross-border price differences.
    • Market Fragmentation: Hindered the EU’s goal of a unified digital market.

10. Engie Group (Tax Rulings and State Aid)

  • Complaint Basis: Benefited from favorable tax rulings that constituted illegal state aid​.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Unfair Competitive Advantage: Other companies operating under normal tax laws faced disadvantages.
    • Loss to Public Finances: Reduced tax revenues for the government.

11. FIFA and UEFA (Super League Case)

  • Complaint Basis: Imposed restrictive rules on clubs attempting to form the Super League, potentially abusing their dominance​.
  • Harms Identified:
    • Stifled Innovation: Prevented new competition in football competitions.
    • Consumer Harm: Limited fans’ options for alternative leagues.

Legal Strategies and Next Steps:

  • Comprehensive Complaints: File formal complaints with the European Commission and national competition authorities against these entities.
  • Stakeholder Collaboration: Engage with consumer protection groups and competitors harmed by these practices to strengthen the cases.
  • Public Advocacy: Highlight harms to the public interest to gain broader support.

The harms in many of these cases are ongoing, justifying urgent legal intervention



i ask:

today is 10 january 2025. using the information you gave me, browse the internet, to find the actual expiry dates,for claiming damages and the judicial review claims , against each the perpetrators?:

Based on the information provided and the current date of January 10, 2025, here are the specific time limits for filing claims for damages and judicial reviews against each of the listed entities:

1. European Commission (State Aid Monitoring)

  • Judicial Review (Article 263 TFEU):
    • Time Limit: 2 months and 10 days from the date of publication or notification of the contested act.
    • Status: Given that the COVID-19-related state aid decisions were primarily made in 2020 and 2021, the window for judicial review has expired.
  • Damages Claim (Article 340 TFEU):
    • Time Limit: Generally interpreted as 5 years from the date the claimant became aware of the damage.
    • Status: If the damage was realized in 2020, the deadline would be in 2025. Therefore, claims may still be viable, depending on the specific dates of awareness.

2. Meta Platforms Inc. (Abuse of Dominance in Data Processing)

  • Damages Claim (Directive 2014/104/EU):
    • Time Limit: 5 years from when the claimant becomes aware of the infringement and the harm suffered.
    • Status: If the infringement was identified in 2021, claims can be filed until 2026.
  • Judicial Review of National Competition Authority’s Decision:
    • Time Limit: Varies by Member State; generally 2-3 months after the decision.
    • Status: Specific deadlines depend on the national authority’s decision dates.

3. České dráhy a.s. (Abuse of Dominance in Rail Transport)

  • Damages Claim (Directive 2014/104/EU):
    • Time Limit: 5 years from awareness of the infringement and harm.
    • Status: If the infringement was recognized in 2020, claims are valid until 2025.
  • Judicial Review of National Authority’s Decision:
    • Time Limit: Typically 2-3 months from notification of the decision.
    • Status: Depends on the specific decision dates.

4. Daimler AG (Trucks Cartel)

  • Damages Claim (Directive 2014/104/EU):
    • Time Limit: 5 years from when the claimant became aware of the harm.
    • Status: The European Commission fined truck manufacturers, including Daimler, in July 2016. Therefore, the deadline for claims would have been in 2021, which has now expired.

5. Lietuvos Geležinkeliai (Lithuanian Railways)

  • Damages Claim (Directive 2014/104/EU):
    • Time Limit: 5 years from knowledge of harm and the infringement.
    • Status: The European Commission fined Lietuvos Geležinkeliai in October 2017. Therefore, the deadline for claims would have been in 2022, which has now expired.
  • Judicial Review (Article 263 TFEU):
    • Time Limit: 2 months and 10 days from the relevant EU decision.
    • Status: The window for judicial review has expired.

6. Unilever Italia (Exclusivity Clauses in Distribution)

  • Damages Claim (Directive 2014/104/EU):
    • Time Limit: 5 years from awareness of harm and infringement.
    • Status: If the infringement was identified in 2020, claims are valid until 2025.
  • Judicial Review of National Decision:
    • Time Limit: Generally 2-3 months from notification of the decision.
    • Status: Depends on the specific decision dates.

7. Bulgarian Energy Holding (BEH) Group

  • Damages Claim (Directive 2014/104/EU):
    • Time Limit: 5 years from knowledge of harm and the infringement.
    • Status: The European Commission fined BEH in December 2018. Therefore, the deadline for claims would be in 2023, which has now expired.
  • Judicial Review of EU Decision (Article 263 TFEU):
    • Time Limit: 2 months and 10 days from the decision date.
    • Status: The window for judicial review has expired.

8. Google (Google Shopping Case)

  • Damages Claim (Directive 2014/104/EU):
    • Time Limit: 5 years from awareness of harm and infringement.
    • Status: The European Commission fined Google in June 2017. Therefore, the deadline for claims would have been in 2022, which has now expired.
  • Judicial Review of Commission Decision:
    • Time Limit: 2 months and 10 days from the date of decision.
    • Status: The window for judicial review has expired.

9. Valve Corporation (Geoblocking Case)

  • Damages Claim (Directive 2014/104/EU):
    • Time Limit: 5 years from knowledge of harm and infringement.
    • Status: The European Commission fined Valve in January 2021. Therefore, claims can be filed until January 2026.
  • Judicial Review of Commission Decision:
    • Time Limit: 2 months and 10 days from the date
Posted by wpMY0dxsz043 in COCOO CASES, 0 comments

complaints.v.eu.budget. audit.rep


As the legal representative for COCOO, an organization dedicated to enforcing competition law, I have reviewed the provided information and conducted further research to identify potential avenues for complaints and claims. Below is a structured analysis addressing each of your queries:

1. Potential Targets for Complaints:

Based on the available information, the following entities may be subject to complaints:

  • Single Resolution Board (SRB): Involved in a legal dispute concerning data protection practices.
  • Community Plant Variety Office (CPVO): Subject to appeals regarding decisions on plant variety rights.

2. Grounds and Supporting Evidence for Complaints:

  • SRB: The complaint involves alleged non-compliance with data protection regulations, as evidenced by the European Data Protection Supervisor’s (EDPS) decisions and subsequent legal proceedings.
  • CPVO: The grounds pertain to disputes over decisions on plant variety rights, with appeals filed by affected parties.

3. Appropriate Forums for Lodging Complaints:

  • SRB: Complaints can be lodged with the European Data Protection Supervisor (EDPS) and, if necessary, appealed to the General Court of the European Union.
  • CPVO: Appeals against CPVO decisions can be filed with the CPVO’s Board of Appeal and, subsequently, with the General Court of the European Union.

Analysis of Each Complaint:

A. Single Resolution Board (SRB):

  • Type of Harm: Potential infringement of data protection rights.
  • Date Harm Started: The initial EDPS decision was on 24 June 2020.
  • Time Limit for Complaint/Damages Claim: Under EU law, actions for annulment must be brought within two months of the contested act’s publication or notification. For damages, the statute of limitations is generally five years from when the harm occurred.
  • Perpetrator: Single Resolution Board (SRB).
  • Victims: Individuals whose data protection rights were potentially violated.

B. Community Plant Variety Office (CPVO):

  • Type of Harm: Disputes over plant variety rights decisions.
  • Date Harm Started: Specific dates vary per case; for instance, the General Court’s judgment was on 19 December 2014.
  • Time Limit for Complaint/Damages Claim: Appeals must be filed within two months of the decision. Damages claims generally have a five-year limitation period.
  • Perpetrator: Community Plant Variety Office (CPVO).
  • Victims: Applicants or holders of plant variety rights adversely affected by CPVO decisions.

Assessment of Time Limits:

  • SRB: As of 12 January 2025, the five-year limitation period for damages claims related to the 2020 decision remains open until 24 June 2025.
  • CPVO: For decisions made on 19 December 2014, the five-year limitation period expired on 19 December 2019. However, if there are more recent decisions, the limitation period may still be open.

Potential Complaints and Claims Still Viable:

  • SRB: Claims for damages related to the 2020 decision are still within the limitation period and can be pursued.
  • CPVO: If there are recent decisions within the past five years, complaints and claims may still be viable.

Victim Identification:

  • Public Interest: General public concerned with adherence to data protection laws.
  • Consumers: Individuals whose personal data may have been mishandled.
  • Competitors: Entities affected by CPVO’s decisions impacting market competition.

Impact on Competition Law and Policy:

  • SRB Case: Non-compliance with data protection regulations can undermine consumer trust, leading to reduced market participation and distorted competition.
  • CPVO Case: Unfair or inconsistent decisions on plant variety rights can hinder innovation and distort market competition by granting undue advantages or imposing unjust barriers.

Draft Letters of Claim for Damages:

Sample Outline for SRB:

[Your Name]
[Your Address]
[City, Postal Code]
[Email Address]
[Phone Number]
[Date]

Subject: Notice of Claim for Damages – Data Protection Infringement by Single Resolution Board

To Whom It May Concern:

I am writing on behalf of [Your Organization], representing [Victim’s Name], to formally notify the Single Resolution Board (SRB) of our intent to seek compensation for damages resulting from the infringement of data protection rights, as identified in the European Data Protection Supervisor’s decision dated 24 June 2020.

Details of the Claim:

  • Nature of Infringement: Unauthorized processing of personal data in violation of [specific data protection laws/regulations].
  • Date of Infringement: [Specific date or period].
  • Impact on Victim: [Detailed description of how the victim was affected, including any financial losses, emotional distress, or other relevant harm].

Legal Basis for the Claim:

  • Relevant Laws Violated: [List applicable data protection laws/regulations].
  • Precedent Cases: [Cite any relevant case law supporting the claim].

Requested Remedies:

  • Compensation Amount: [Specify the amount sought as damages].
  • Additional Actions: [Any other remedies sought, such as corrective measures or formal apologies].

We request a response within [reasonable timeframe, e.g., 30 days] to discuss this matter further and explore potential resolutions. Failure to respond or reach an amicable settlement may result in legal proceedings to enforce our client’s rights



i  ask:
you are the lawyer of the cocoo, an organisation that enforces competition law. read the attachment in depth, looking for points of law and points of fact, and insights into actual or potential competition violations. what companies or organisations (example, the eu commission) can we file a complaint about?. For example, the the commission fail to enforce competition law, by tacking any potential competition violations?. Who was harmed as a result?: the public interest, consumers, competitors? what were the harms? any negative externalities?. before you give an answer, go online and browse for relevant information: legal precedents, news, insights, etc to strengthen our legal position and evidence…. GIVE ME A FULL LIST OF COMPANIES AND ORGANISATIONS THAT HARM COMPETITION LAW. WE MUST COMPLAIN ABOUT THEM. WHAT HARMS WERE INFLICTED? ARE THE HARMS ONGOING? NAME THE PERPETRATORS OF THOSE HARMS TO COMPETITION LAW, CONSUMER LAW, AND PUBLIC INTEREST

chatgpt:

As the legal representative of COCOO, an organization dedicated to enforcing competition law, it is imperative to identify entities that have engaged in practices detrimental to market competition, consumer welfare, and the public interest. Based on recent legal precedents and enforcement actions, the following companies and organizations have been implicated in competition law violations:

  1. Valve Corporation and Five Video Game Publishers:
    • Perpetrators: Valve Corporation, alongside publishers such as Focus Home, Koch Media, ZeniMax, Bandai Namco, and Capcom.
    • Violation: Engagement in geo-blocking practices that restricted cross-border sales of PC video games within the European Economic Area (EEA), infringing Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU).
    • Harm Inflicted:
      • Consumers: Deprivation of the benefits of the EU Digital Single Market, leading to reduced access to a wider range of games and potential price disparities.
      • Competitors: Unfair competitive advantage by limiting market access based on geographic location.
    • Ongoing Harm: The General Court upheld the European Commission’s decision on 27 September 2023, indicating that the anti-competitive effects were addressed through regulatory action.
  2. Asus, Denon & Marantz, Philips, and Pioneer:
    • Perpetrators: The aforementioned consumer electronics manufacturers.
    • Violation: Imposition of fixed or minimum resale prices on their online retailers, breaching EU competition rules.
    • Harm Inflicted:
      • Consumers: Artificially inflated prices for electronics due to restricted pricing freedom for retailers.
      • Competitors: Independent retailers faced constraints in setting competitive prices, hindering fair competition.
    • Ongoing Harm: The European Commission fined these companies in 2018, and the anti-competitive practices were expected to cease following the enforcement action.
  3. Illumina Inc.:
    • Perpetrator: Illumina Inc., a U.S.-based gene-sequencing company.
    • Violation: Proceeding with the acquisition of GRAIL, a cancer-test maker, without prior notification and approval from the European Commission, contravening EU merger regulations.
    • Harm Inflicted:
      • Public Interest: Potential reduction in innovation and competition in the genomic sequencing market, which could adversely affect healthcare advancements and pricing.
    • Ongoing Harm: The European Court of Justice ruled against the European Commission’s jurisdiction in this case on 3 September 2024, limiting the Commission’s ability to scrutinize similar mergers.

Potential Complaints Against Regulatory Bodies:

  • European Commission:
    • Allegation: In certain instances, the Commission’s enforcement actions have been challenged and overturned, raising concerns about the effectiveness and appropriateness of its regulatory oversight.
    • Harm Inflicted:
      • Public Interest: Ineffective enforcement may lead to unchecked anti-competitive practices, harming consumers and market integrity.
    • Ongoing Harm: Recent court rulings suggest potential lapses in enforcement, necessitating a review of the Commission’s procedures and decision-making processes.

Recommendations for COCOO:

  • Investigate and Monitor: Continue to monitor the activities of the aforementioned companies to ensure compliance with competition laws.
  • Engage with Regulatory Bodies: Liaise with the European Commission to address any enforcement gaps and advocate for more robust regulatory frameworks.
  • Educate and Advocate: Raise awareness among consumers and industry stakeholders about the importance of competition law compliance and the avenues available for reporting violations.

By addressing these issues, COCOO can play a pivotal role in safeguarding market competition, protecting consumer interests, and promoting fair business practices

Posted by wpMY0dxsz043 in COCOO CASES, 0 comments

cocoo v EC.CMA.CNMC.google.visa.mastercard: CARD payments/interventions/digitmarkets

As legal counsel for COCOO, an organization dedicated to enforcing competition law, I have carefully reviewed the information regarding price interventions in the card market, particularly focusing on the European Commission’s (EC) actions and their implications. Below is a detailed analysis addressing your queries:

1. Potential Entities for Filing Complaints:

  • European Commission (EC): The EC’s implementation of price interventions, such as interchange fee caps and surcharge bans, has been criticized for lacking clear criteria and periodic reviews.
  • Member State Authorities (e.g., Spain): National authorities responsible for enforcing these interventions may also be subject to scrutiny if they have implemented measures without adequate assessment of their impact on competition and consumers.

2. Grounds and Supporting Evidence for Complaints:

  • Lack of Clear Criteria and Justification: The EC’s price interventions reportedly do not stipulate clear criteria for their justification or duration, nor require periodic reviews. This lack of transparency can lead to inefficiencies and potential market distortions.
  • Potential Negative Impact on Consumers: The EC has been unable to demonstrate that the positive effects of certain interventions, particularly those related to card payments, clearly outweigh the negative consequences for consumers.
  • Insufficient Monitoring and Data Access: The absence of an effective monitoring system and lack of access to relevant data hinder the assessment of the impact of these interventions, raising concerns about their effectiveness and unintended consequences.

3. Appropriate Forums for Lodging Complaints:

  • European Ombudsman: Given that the complaints pertain to the actions of the European Commission, the European Ombudsman is the appropriate body to address issues related to maladministration within EU institutions.
  • European Court of Justice (ECJ): For legal challenges concerning the validity or application of EU measures, cases can be brought before the ECJ.

Analysis of Harm and Time Limits:

  • Type of Harm: Potential market distortions, inefficiencies, and adverse effects on consumers due to poorly designed price interventions.
  • Date Harm Started: The specific dates would correspond to the implementation dates of the respective price interventions.
  • Time Limit to File a Complaint or Claim for Damages: Under EU law, actions for annulment must be brought within two months of the publication of the measure, while claims for damages have a five-year limitation period from the date the damage occurred.
  • Perpetrators and Victims:
    • Perpetrators: European Commission and relevant national authorities responsible for implementing the interventions.
    • Victims: Consumers, merchants, and potentially other market participants adversely affected by the interventions.

Assessment of Time Limits for Claims:

  • If the price interventions were implemented within the past five years, there may still be an opportunity to file claims for damages. However, for actions seeking annulment of the measures, the two-month limitation period has likely expired.

Potential Reasons for Lack of Claims:

  • Lack of Awareness: Victims may be unaware of the negative impacts or their rights to challenge the measures.
  • Collective Action Challenges: Individual consumers or taxpayers may lack the standing or resources to initiate claims on behalf of a broader group.
  • Perceived Futility: There may be a perception that challenging EU institutions is unlikely to succeed.

Role of COCOO:

  • COCOO, as an organization dedicated to upholding competition law and protecting public interest, is well-positioned to advocate on behalf of consumers and the public. By leveraging its standing, COCOO can initiate actions to address potential competition violations and seek remedies for the harm caused.

Conclusion:

While the window for certain legal actions may have closed, there remains an opportunity for COCOO to pursue claims for damages resulting from the EC’s price interventions, provided they fall within the applicable limitation periods. By acting on behalf of affected consumers and the public interest, COCOO can address potential competition violations and seek appropriate remedies.

Note: This analysis is based on the information available as of January 12, 2025. For precise legal advice, further detailed examination of the specific interventions and their implementation dates is recommended


i ask:

you are the lawyer of the cocoo, an organisation that enforces competition law. read the attachment in depth, looking for points of law and points of fact, and insights into actual or potential competition violations. what companies or organisations (example, the eu commission) can we file a complaint about?. For example, the the commission fail to enforce competition law, by tacking any potential competition violations?. Who was harmed as a result?: the public interest, consumers, competitors? what were the harms? any negative externalities?. before you give an answer, go online and browse for relevant information: legal precedents, news, insights, etc to strengthen our legal position and evidence…..READ THE ATTACHMENT AND GIVE ME A FULL LIST OF COMPANIES AND ORGANISATIONS THAT HARM COMPETITION LAW. WE MUST COMPLAIN ABOUT THEM. WHAT HARMS WERE INFLICTED? ARE THE HARMS ONGOING? NAME THE PERPETRATORS OF THOSE HARMS TO COMPETITION LAW, CONSUMER LAW, AND PUBLIC INTEREST

The audit report identifies several companies and organizations responsible for anti-competitive behavior or for failures in ensuring fair competition in the EU’s digital payments market. The following entities and associated harms to competition, consumer interests, and the public interest have been detailed:


1. Visa and Mastercard (International Card Schemes)

  • Harm to Competition: High market share (90%) in cross-border payment markets creates significant barriers to entry, fostering limited competition.
  • Consumer Harm: Elevated interchange fees lead to higher merchant service charges, ultimately borne by consumers.
  • Ongoing Harms: Price interventions, such as interchange fee caps, are not consistently reviewed, leading to potential distortions in the market​.

2. Payment Service Providers (PSPs)

  • Examples: Major PSPs across the EU include banks and specialized payment institutions.
  • Harm to Competition: Lack of standardization in open banking interfaces stifles competition, particularly affecting small third-party providers.
  • Consumer/Public Harm: Reduced innovation and fragmented market create higher costs and less accessible payment options​.

3. The European Commission

  • Harm to Competition and Public Interest: Delays in reviewing and implementing regulatory frameworks, such as the Payment Services Directive (PSD2), and lack of enforcement in addressing discriminatory payment account practices.
  • Consumer/Public Harm: Consumers and businesses continue to face barriers in cross-border payments, leading to inefficiencies and increased costs​.

4. National Card Schemes

  • Examples: Bancontact (Belgium), CB (France), Girocard (Germany).
  • Harm to Competition: These schemes dominate domestic markets and resist integration with international standards, creating fragmented markets that impede cross-border competition​.

5. European Banking Authority (EBA)

  • Harm to Competition: Insufficient guidance and supervision of open banking frameworks hinder consistent implementation.
  • Consumer/Public Harm: A lack of reliable data impairs the ability to assess the effectiveness of competition and consumer protection measures​.

Summary of Harms:

  • To Consumers: Higher prices, reduced access to innovative payment solutions.
  • To Competition: Barriers to entry, limited interoperability of payment systems.
  • To Public Interest: Undermined goals of a unified and efficient digital market in the EU.

Recommendations for Complaints:

  • File complaints against Visa, Mastercard, and dominant PSPs for anti-competitive practices.
  • Advocate for stronger enforcement by the European Commission and EBA to address regulatory gaps and monitoring deficiencies.

finextra.com   >>   has raised concerns over how the EU goes about price interventions in the card market and its approach to open banking data sharing.  Digital payments for retail sales in the EU more than doubled in value between 2017 and 2023, surpassing €1 trillion.   These digital payments are considered crucial for the EU’s internal market to function smoothly, especially across borders, meaning that the body has responsibility for ensuring that they operate efficiently and effectively.   In a report, the European Court of Auditors says that EU’s approach to digital payments has helped to make them “safer, faster and cheaper for users”.   However, the report raises concerns about the EU’s approach to price interventions when it comes to the interchange fee cap for card payments and the surcharge ban on card and Sepa payments.  Ildikó Gáll-Pelcz, ECA Member in charge of the audit, says: “We found that the basic legal acts on digital payments do not stipulate clear criteria for assessing whether price interventions are justified, or how long they should apply. There are also no requirements for periodic reviews. “For some of the interventions linked to card payments, the European Commission could not demonstrate that the positive effects for consumers clearly outweigh the negative ones.”   In addition, the impact of the EU’s digital-payment policies remains largely unknown because the Commission has not put in place an effective monitoring system and, more importantly, lacks access to the relevant data, says the report.   Elsewhere, the court queries the EU’s open banking framework’s obligation on firms to provide third-party providers with access to payment user data free of charge. This, “may discourage account data holders from providing high-quality service”.  The report also flags the lack of standardised APIs, hindering third-party providers from using those data.


need from you is the list of organisations and companies that violated competition law etc, and the date of such violation, and whether the violation is still ongoing today. Only if you collect this information , you can then calculate the dates that the time limits expire for both judicial review and for damages claims
ChatGPT said:

As of January 10, 2025, the following entities have been identified for potential violations of competition law within the EU’s digital payments market:

1. Visa and Mastercard

  • Violation Details: Both companies have been under investigation for imposing fees that may harm retailers. The European Commission initiated a probe in September 2024, sending questionnaires to retailers and payment service providers to assess the impact of these fees.
  • Ongoing Status: The investigation is active, and no final decision has been made as of this date.

2. Payment Service Providers (PSPs)

  • Violation Details: Specific PSPs have been implicated in anti-competitive practices, particularly concerning the lack of standardization in open banking interfaces, which stifles competition. However, detailed information on individual PSPs and the exact dates of violations is not readily available.
  • Ongoing Status: Without specific details, it’s unclear whether these violations are ongoing.

3. The European Commission

  • Violation Details: The Commission has faced criticism for delays in reviewing and implementing regulatory frameworks, such as the Payment Services Directive (PSD2), potentially impacting fair competition. However, these are procedural delays rather than direct violations of competition law.
  • Ongoing Status: Efforts are ongoing to address these delays.

4. National Card Schemes

  • Violation Details: Schemes like Bancontact (Belgium), CB (France), and Girocard (Germany) have been noted for dominating domestic markets and resisting integration with international standards, leading to market fragmentation. Specific violation dates are not documented.
  • Ongoing Status: The market dynamics suggest that these practices may still be in place.

5. European Banking Authority (EBA)

  • Violation Details: The EBA has been criticized for insufficient guidance and supervision of open banking frameworks, which may hinder consistent implementation. However, this pertains more to regulatory oversight than direct competition law violations.
  • Ongoing Status: The EBA continues its regulatory functions, with ongoing discussions about improving guidance.

Calculating Limitation Periods:

  • Damages Claims: Under the EU Damages Directive (Directive 2014/104/EU), claimants have a minimum of five years to bring damages actions, starting from the date they become aware of the infringement, the harm caused, and the identity of the infringer. The period does not commence until the infringement has ceased. If a competition authority initiates proceedings, the limitation period is suspended until at least one year after the decision becomes final.
  • Judicial Review Applications: These should be filed promptly, typically within three months from when the grounds for the application first arose. Delays can prejudice the respondent or third parties, and applications made after the deadline are generally disfavored.

Conclusion:

Given the complexities and the need for precise timing, it’s advisable to consult legal counsel to determine the exact expiry dates for initiating claims against these entities, tailored to the specific circumstances of each case.


i ask:
READ THE ATTACHMENT AND GIVE ME A FULL LIST OF COMPANIES AND ORGANISATIONS THAT HARM COMPETITION LAW. WE MUST COMPLAIN ABOUT THEM. WHAT HARMS WERE INFLICTED? ARE THE HARMS ONGOING? NAME THE PERPETRATORS OF THOSE HARMS TO COMPETITION LAW, CONSUMER LAW, AND PUBLIC INTEREST

chatgpt:

The audit report identifies several companies and organizations responsible for anti-competitive behavior or for failures in ensuring fair competition in the EU’s digital payments market. The following entities and associated harms to competition, consumer interests, and the public interest have been detailed:

1. Visa and Mastercard (International Card Schemes)

  • Harm to Competition: High market share (90%) in cross-border payment markets creates significant barriers to entry, fostering limited competition.
  • Consumer Harm: Elevated interchange fees lead to higher merchant service charges, ultimately borne by consumers.
  • Ongoing Harms: Price interventions, such as interchange fee caps, are not consistently reviewed, leading to potential distortions in the market​.

2. Payment Service Providers (PSPs)

  • Examples: Major PSPs across the EU include banks and specialized payment institutions.
  • Harm to Competition: Lack of standardization in open banking interfaces stifles competition, particularly affecting small third-party providers.
  • Consumer/Public Harm: Reduced innovation and fragmented market create higher costs and less accessible payment options​.

3. The European Commission

  • Harm to Competition and Public Interest: Delays in reviewing and implementing regulatory frameworks, such as the Payment Services Directive (PSD2), and lack of enforcement in addressing discriminatory payment account practices.
  • Consumer/Public Harm: Consumers and businesses continue to face barriers in cross-border payments, leading to inefficiencies and increased costs​.

4. National Card Schemes

  • Examples: Bancontact (Belgium), CB (France), Girocard (Germany).
  • Harm to Competition: These schemes dominate domestic markets and resist integration with international standards, creating fragmented markets that impede cross-border competition​.

5. European Banking Authority (EBA)

  • Harm to Competition: Insufficient guidance and supervision of open banking frameworks hinder consistent implementation.
  • Consumer/Public Harm: A lack of reliable data impairs the ability to assess the effectiveness of competition and consumer protection measures​.

Summary of Harms:

  • To Consumers: Higher prices, reduced access to innovative payment solutions.
  • To Competition: Barriers to entry, limited interoperability of payment systems.
  • To Public Interest: Undermined goals of a unified and efficient digital market in the EU.

Recommendations for Complaints:

  • File complaints against Visa, Mastercard, and dominant PSPs for anti-competitive practices.
  • Advocate for stronger enforcement by the European Commission and EBA to address regulatory gaps and monitoring deficiencies

i ask:

in connection with this legal matter, are there , today, any ongoing investigations and litigation against any company or any competition authority or public body ?

As of January 10, 2025, there are several ongoing investigations and legal proceedings concerning potential violations of competition law within the digital payments sector. Notably:

1. Visa and Mastercard

  • Investigation Details: In September 2024, the European Commission initiated an antitrust investigation into Visa and Mastercard’s fee structures, particularly focusing on scheme fees charged to retailers. The Commission distributed questionnaires to retailers and payment service providers to assess whether these fees negatively impact competition and consumer welfare.
  • Current Status: The investigation is active, with both companies cooperating by providing the requested information.

2. Apple

  • Investigation Details: The European Commission has been examining Apple’s practices related to its mobile payment system, Apple Pay. Concerns were raised about Apple’s restrictions on access to the Near Field Communication (NFC) technology embedded in iPhones, potentially limiting competition in mobile wallets.
  • Current Status: In June 2024, Apple reached a settlement with the European Commission, agreeing to open its NFC technology to third-party mobile wallet providers. This commitment is legally binding for ten years, with potential fines for non-compliance.

3. Digital Markets Act (DMA) Enforcement

  • Investigation Details: The European Commission has initiated non-compliance investigations under the Digital Markets Act against major tech companies, including Alphabet (Google), Apple, and Meta (Facebook). These investigations focus on practices such as self-preferencing, anti-steering rules, and conditions imposed on developers, which may hinder competition.
  • Current Status: These investigations are ongoing, aiming to ensure compliance with the DMA’s provisions designed to promote fair competition in digital markets.

Conclusion:

The digital payments sector remains under close scrutiny by European competition authorities, with active investigations and enforcement actions targeting potential anti-competitive practices by major industry players. These proceedings underscore the EU’s commitment to maintaining fair competition and protecting consumer interests in the rapidly evolving digital economy.


I ASK:
in connection with this legal matter, are there , today, any ongoing investigations and litigation against any company or any competition authority or public body ?

As of January 10, 2025, there are several ongoing investigations and legal proceedings concerning potential violations of competition law within the digital payments sector. Notably:

1. Visa and Mastercard

  • Investigation Details: In September 2024, the European Commission initiated an antitrust investigation into Visa and Mastercard’s fee structures, particularly focusing on scheme fees charged to retailers. The Commission distributed questionnaires to retailers and payment service providers to assess whether these fees negatively impact competition and consumer welfare.Reuters
  • Current Status: The investigation is active, with both companies cooperating by providing the requested information.

2. Apple

  • Investigation Details: The European Commission has been examining Apple’s practices related to its mobile payment system, Apple Pay. Concerns were raised about Apple’s restrictions on access to the Near Field Communication (NFC) technology embedded in iPhones, potentially limiting competition in mobile wallets. Financial Times
  • Current Status: In June 2024, Apple reached a settlement with the European Commission, agreeing to open its NFC technology to third-party mobile wallet providers. This commitment is legally binding for ten years, with potential fines for non-compliance. The Wall Street Journal

3. Digital Markets Act (DMA) Enforcement

  • Investigation Details: The European Commission has initiated non-compliance investigations under the Digital Markets Act against major tech companies, including Alphabet (Google), Apple, and Meta (Facebook). These investigations focus on practices such as self-preferencing, anti-steering rules, and conditions imposed on developers, which may hinder competition. Digital Markets Act
  • Current Status: These investigations are ongoing, aiming to ensure compliance with the DMA’s provisions designed to promote fair competition in digital markets.

Conclusion:

The digital payments sector remains under close scrutiny by European competition authorities, with active investigations and enforcement actions targeting potential anti-competitive practices by major industry players. These proceedings underscore the EU’s commitment to maintaining fair competition and protecting consumer interests in the rapidly evolving digital economy

 

Posted by wpMY0dxsz043 in COCOO CASES, 0 comments

complaint v DOJ

WRITE COMPLAINTS + 3PINT LETTER (samnote) TO THE LAWYERS OF all PARTIES + MEDIATION OFFER + PRO-BONO NON-RESERVED LEGAL ADVICE OFFER

EX: CAT:  coll.foc V GOOGLE:     notes: 3pint.application2cat       >> the coll.claim was granted permission and google chose not to appeal (to COA) >> cocoo will submit the coll.claim parties a proposed letter of intervention as a 3pint in support of Google….The class action lawsuit against Google, brought by Ad Tech Collective Action LLP, is filed under the Competition Appeal Tribunal (CAT) with case numbers 1572/7/7/22 and 1582/7/7/23Catribunal    A certification hearing was held from May 8 to 10, 2024, during which the CAT approved the claim to proceed towards trial.  Catribunal   The trial is anticipated to commence after 2025, though an exact date has not been set.   Reuters   The lawsuit alleges that Google abused its dominant position in the online advertising market, causing financial losses to UK publishers. The claim seeks damages up to £13.6 billionReuters



Some appropriate approaches could include:

  1. Demonstrating pro-competitive benefits of Google’s integrated ad tech stack
  2. Providing evidence of dynamic competition in digital markets
  3. Arguing for the application of effects-based analysis rather than rigid market definitions
  4. Highlighting consumer benefits and innovation resulting from Google’s practices

The focus should be on constructive engagement with regulators to address concerns while maintaining ethical and legal integrity.


Antitrust Division
U.S. Department of Justice
950 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20530-0001

08.JANUARY.2025

Sent via email to antitrust.complaints@usdoj.gov.

Formal Complaint Challenging DOJ Decisions in Google Search and Ad Tech CasesDear Sir/Madam,

On behalf of the COCOO, we are writing to formally challenge the Department of Justice’s decisions in two cases against Google: the Search case ruling of August 5, 2024, and the ongoing Ad Tech case. We believe these decisions are based on flawed economic analyses and may result in unintended negative consequences for the digital economy and the public interest

Misapplication of Monopoly Standards

The DOJ’s approach relies heavily on narrow market definition and traditional measures of dominance that fail to account for the dynamic, multi-sided nature of digital markets. As Professor Louis Kaplow argues, market definition often conflates empirical questions of market power with legal policy judgments

1. The digital advertising ecosystem is highly dynamic, with competition from diverse platforms like Meta, Amazon, and TikTok, which the DOJ’s narrow focus fails to capture.

2.Overlooking Consumer Choice and Innovation

The rulings underestimate users’ ability to switch search engines and ad tech providers easily. Google’s market position is primarily due to superior product quality and continuous innovation, not anticompetitive practices. Professor Massimo Motta emphasizes the importance of dynamic efficiency in competition policy, particularly in markets driven by innovation

3.Inadequacy of Traditional Competition Tools

The Small but Significant and Non-transitory Increase in Price (SSNIP) test is inapplicable in zero-price markets like Google Search. This methodology overlooks the multi-sided nature of digital advertising platforms, where competitive dynamics depend more on data-driven efficiencies and advertiser satisfaction than on direct consumer pricing.

4.Pro-Competitive Benefits Ignored

The investigations overlook the pro-competitive benefits of Google’s integrated ad tech stack and revenue-sharing agreements (RSAs), which enhance efficiency, reduce transaction costs, and foster innovation. In Intel v. Commission (Case T-286/09), the General Court acknowledged that such agreements may have legitimate pro-competitive justifications.

5. Lack of Consumer Harm

The cases lack concrete evidence of consumer harm—a core requirement for antitrust violations. Google’s practices sustain free content for users and higher revenues for publishers, benefiting the broader digital economy. In Verizon v. Trinko (2004), the U.S. Supreme Court held that antitrust law does not obligate a dominant firm to lower natural barriers or aid competitors, especially in high-cost, innovation-driven markets.

  1. Flawed Counterfactual Analysis

The DOJ’s speculative counterfactuals fail to reflect real-world market dynamics, underestimating competition from other platforms and misinterpreting Google’s role in enhancing ad tech efficiency.RecommendationsWe urge the DOJ to reconsider its approach in both cases:

  1. Adopt a more nuanced, effects-based analysis that considers the realities of digital markets.
  2. Recognize the role of innovation and quality in shaping market dynamics.
  3. Consider the potential negative impacts of overly aggressive enforcement on the broader digital economy, including potential harm to small publishers and advertisers.

We remain available to provide further information or clarification on these matters.Sincerely,[Your Name]
[Your Title]
[Your Organization]

 

 



The Competition & Consumer Organisation Party Limited (The COCOO). UK Companies House Registration Number: 15466919. Address: 23 Village Way, Beckenham. Postcode: BR33NA.United Kingdom. Email: contact@cocoo.uk

05.01.2025

PROCEDURE

Third parties do not have standing to challenge a cma.ec.pus decision that is not final, (like issuing a SO = deciding to start an investigation)…However, interested third parties can submit comments or evidence to the CMA during its investigation.

• complaint (2cma) v cma decision (did cma condemn google?) >> later on, i can use the cma decis to FOC4dams4.bsd,  in a different case
ex: sept.24: cma decis: SOS issued to Google:  the Statement of objections sets out how Google may have broken competition law by using its dominance to favour its own ad tech services in open-display advertising.  The CMA will now carefully consider representations from Google before reaching its final decision.
https://www.gov.uk/government/news/cma-objects-to-googles-ad-tech-practices-in-bid-to-help-uk-advertisers-and-publishers

• -complaint (2cma/ec) v any other U.V./illegal decis/omis by a regulator/PUS (ex: cocoo v reg/pus decis, on basis that is U.V./illegal becos enforces clp in a manner that is beyond the statutory powers conferred (by 1leg) to that reg/pus
– Later on, I have the option to start a different (but parallel) case. both have in common the same cma/ec decis. In this new case, I FOC4dams4.BSD (breach.stat.duty)
-ex: sep.24: ec decis to issue SOS to Google

https://www.justice.gov/atr/complaint-center:
-ex:US DOJ v Google (Search): 5 August 2024 – Judge Mehta’s ruling that Google illegally maintained a monopoly in online search.[1] Google is planning to appeal the decision, which could impact the timings of the case.
-ex:US DOJ v Google (Ad Tech): This is the second DOJ case currently unfolding against Google but this time against its abuses in the Ad Tech industry

• -complaint  (2ec) v member decis that violates EULAW >> later on, i can use the ec decis to FOC4dams4.bsd,  in a different case
EX: CNMC/SPANISH.PUS DECISIONS AGAINST GOOGLE>>EX: THE CNMC ESTA INVESTIGANDO GOOGLE. DESDE JUN.2024 TIENE UN máximo de 18 meses para la instrucción del expediente y para su resolución.La CNMC inicia un expediente sancionador contra Google por posibles prácticas anticompetitivas que afectarían a editoriales de publicaciones de prensa y agencias de noticias españolas. Las conductas investigadas podrían suponer la explotación abusiva por parte de Google de su posición de dominio en el mercado español.
• El abuso analizado consistiría en la imposición de condiciones inequitativas a las editoriales de publicaciones de prensa y agencias de noticias españolas.
• Las prácticas investigadas también incluirían posibles actos de competencia desleal que podrían afectar al interés público por falsear la libre competencia.
La CNMC ha iniciado un expediente sancionador contra Google LLC, Google Ireland Ltd., Google Spain, S.L. (Google) y contra su matriz Alphabet Inc., por prácticas restrictivas de la competencia prohibidas por los artículos 2 y 3 de la Ley 15/2007, de 3 de julio, de Defensa de la Competencia (LDC) y en el artículo 102 del Tratado de Funcionamiento de la Unión Europea (TFUE) (S/0013/22). Por una parte, la CNMC investiga una serie de prácticas que podrían suponer un abuso de la posición de dominio de Google con respecto a las editoriales de publicaciones de prensa y agencias de noticias establecidas en España. En particular, estas prácticas consistirían la posible imposición de condiciones comerciales no equitativas a las editoriales de publicaciones de prensa y agencias de noticias establecidas en España para la explotación de su contenido protegido por derechos de propiedad intelectual.
Por otra parte, las conductas investigadas también incluirían prácticas que constituirían actos de competencia desleal que podrían falsear la libre competencia con afectación al interés público. Estas prácticas podrían infringir el apartado tercero del artículo 129 bis del Real Decreto Legislativo 1/1996, de 12 de abril, por el que se aprueba el texto refundido de la Ley de Propiedad Intelectual, y podrían suponer la explotación de la situación de dependencia económica respecto a Google en que se encontrarían las editoriales de publicaciones de prensa y agencias de noticias establecidas en España.
Este expediente tiene su origen en una denuncia recibida en la CNMC por parte del Centro Español de Derechos Reprográficos (CEDRO).
A la vista de dicha denuncia y de la información recabada en el marco de la fase de información reservada, la Dirección de Competencia de la CNMC considera que existen indicios racionales de la comisión, por parte de Google, de posibles infracciones de los artículos 2 y 3 de la LDC, así como del artículo 102 del TFUE. La incoación de este expediente no prejuzga el resultado final de la investigación. Se abre ahora un periodo máximo de 18 meses para la instrucción del expediente y para su resolución por la CNMC.

• -complaint  (2ec) v privco/pus.ec… decis that violates CLP >> later, i can use the ec decis to FOC4dams4.bsd,  in a different case
-EX:  (case:proSpain): cocoo complaints against the ECT agreement, as IS CONTRARY TO CLP…, as it promotes stealth.cons and cartel behaviour by the smaller fish that circle the sharks >> COCOO: IF EC ALLOWS ECT, EC WOULD BE ACTING U.V./ILLEGAL
-EX: (case:proGoogle): cocoo complaints against the google ad.rivals (the claimants are privcos,little fish, that, to thrive, behave as a de-facto cartel ( an implied sust.ua that fails at least 1 of the 4Exempt.Conds.) + stealth.consolid. driver

• I COMPLAIN V EC =  complaint (2ec) v ec decision >> later, i can use the ec decis to FOC4dams4.bsd, in a different case
-EX: cocoo complaints to ec for its decis: https://www.gov.uk/government/news/cma-objects-to-googles-ad-tech-practices-in-bid-to-help-uk-advertisers-and-publishers

• -complaint2 (euomb/ukparlomb) v privco/pus…that violates CLP or EU.uk LAW…but first, i need to complain to the eu.privco/pus. Omb decis is only a recommendation. no teeth.
EX: COMPLAINT V THE EC.CMA.SOSBT… DECIS on any of my complaints listed above.

============================================

PERPLEXITY

[Your Law Firm’s Letterhead]
[Date]Competition and Markets Authority
The Cabot
25 Cabot Square
London E14 4QZ
United KingdomSubject: Formal Complaint Challenging CMA’s Decision to Investigate Google’s Ad Tech PracticesDear Sir/Madam,I am writing on behalf of Google LLC to formally challenge the Competition and Markets Authority’s (CMA) decision to investigate Google’s advertising technology (ad tech) practices. We believe this investigation is based on flawed premises and outdated economic frameworks that fail to account for the dynamic nature of digital markets.
Grounds for Complaint
1. Misapplication of Market Definition
The CMA’s approach relies heavily on narrow market definition, which is inappropriate for assessing competition in multi-sided digital platforms. As Professor Louis Kaplow argues, market definition often conflates empirical questions of market power with legal policy judgments
1
. The digital advertising ecosystem is highly dynamic, with competition from diverse platforms like Meta, Amazon, and TikTok, which the CMA’s narrow focus fails to capture.
2. Misinterpretation of Market Shares
High market shares in digital markets do not inherently equate to anticompetitive harm. In United Brands v. Commission (Case 27/76), the European Court of Justice emphasized that market definition must reflect economic realities. The CMA’s reliance on rigid market shares ignores the innovation-driven competition that shapes user preferences in the ad tech industry.
3. Inadequacy of Traditional Competition Tools
The Small but Significant and Non-transitory Increase in Price (SSNIP) test is inapplicable in zero-price markets like Google Search. This methodology overlooks the multi-sided nature of digital advertising platforms, where competitive dynamics depend more on data-driven efficiencies and advertiser satisfaction than on direct consumer pricing.
4. Pro-Competitive Justifications Overlooked
The CMA has failed to adequately consider the pro-competitive benefits of Google’s practices:a) Revenue-Sharing Agreements (RSAs): These agreements foster innovation and efficiency, benefiting consumers and device manufacturers. In Intel v. Commission (Case T-286/09), the General Court acknowledged that such agreements may have legitimate pro-competitive justifications.b) Integrated Ad Tech Stack: Google’s vertically integrated stack enhances efficiency, reduces transaction costs, and improves ad relevance, maximizing publisher revenue and advertiser ROI.
5. Lack of Consumer Harm
The investigation lacks concrete evidence of consumer harm—a core requirement for antitrust violations. Google’s practices sustain free content for users and higher revenues for publishers, benefiting the broader digital economy. In Verizon v. Trinko (2004), the U.S. Supreme Court held that antitrust law does not obligate a dominant firm to lower natural barriers or aid competitors, especially in high-cost, innovation-driven markets.
6. Flawed Counterfactual Analysis
The CMA’s speculative counterfactuals fail to reflect real-world market dynamics, underestimating competition from other platforms and misinterpreting Google’s role in enhancing ad tech efficiency.
Risks of Overregulation
The CMA’s approach poses significant risks:
• Harm to SMEs and publishers: Structural remedies could disproportionately harm small publishers and advertisers by increasing costs and operational complexity.
• Chilling effect on innovation: Aggressive enforcement could deter investment in the UK’s digital economy, discouraging innovation by both Google and its competitors.
• International policy divergence: The CMA’s approach risks misalignment with U.S. DOJ and EU investigations, potentially creating regulatory uncertainty that undermines the UK’s competitiveness as a tech hub.
Conclusion and Recommendations
We urge the CMA to reconsider its decision to investigate and adopt a more balanced approach that reflects the complexities of the ad tech market. We recommend:
• Revisiting the market definition to align with economic realities.
• Recognizing the pro-competitive justifications of Google’s practices.
• Adopting an effects-based analysis that evaluates actual harm to consumers and competitors.
• Considering the broader impact on innovation and the UK’s digital economy.
We remain committed to engaging in further discussions and providing additional evidence to assist in a fair and proportionate resolution.Yours faithfully,[Your Full Name]
[Your Position]
[Your Contact Information]
[Your Law Firm’s Name]
Share
Rewrite

========================================================

GPT:
Letter of COMPLAINT V cma

Here is the refined Letter of Complaint in favor of Google, integrating the key arguments and insights provided, including Kaplow’s critiques, Motta’s frameworks, and relevant case law:
[Your Address]
[City, State, ZIP]
[Date]
The Competition and Markets Authority (CMA)
The Cabot
25 Cabot Square
London E14 4QZ
United Kingdom
Dear Sir/Madam,
Subject: Formal Complaint Challenging CMA’s Findings on Google’s Ad Tech Practices
I am writing to formally challenge the CMA’s provisional findings against Google concerning its advertising technology (ad tech) practices, which I believe rely on an outdated and flawed economic framework. Specifically, the CMA’s approach hinges on rigid market definition and traditional measures of dominance that fail to account for the dynamic, multi-sided nature of digital markets. This letter provides an alternative analysis based on contemporary economic principles, supported by insights from legal and academic authorities such as Louis Kaplow and Massimo Motta.
1. Critique of Market Definition and Reliance on Market Shares
The CMA’s assessment of Google’s market power rests heavily on defining a narrow market and associating high market shares with dominance. However, as Professor Louis Kaplow argues, market definition conflates two distinct inquiries:
• The empirical question of how much market power exists, and
• The legal policy judgment of how much market power should trigger liability.
Such reliance on rigid market shares ignores the dynamic competition that exists in digital markets, including competitors such as Amazon and Meta. High market shares do not inherently equate to anticompetitive harm, especially in a market where switching costs for consumers remain negligible. Furthermore, market shares in digital ecosystems fail to capture innovation-driven competition, which is the primary force shaping user preference.
2. Inadequacy of the SSNIP Test in Zero-Price Markets
The Small but Significant and Non-transitory Increase in Price (SSNIP) test, used to define markets, is entirely inapplicable in zero-price markets like Google Search. This methodology overlooks the multi-sided nature of digital advertising platforms, where competitive dynamics depend more on data-driven efficiencies and advertiser satisfaction than on direct consumer pricing.
Alternative Approach: The CMA should instead adopt an effects-based analysis, which evaluates actual harm to consumers and competitors. This would include assessing price-cost margins, diversion ratios, and the broader economic impact of Google’s practices on innovation and consumer welfare.
3. Pro-Competitive Justifications of Revenue-Sharing Agreements (RSAs)
The CMA criticizes Google’s RSAs with device manufacturers and browsers as exclusionary. However, these agreements serve a legitimate purpose by ensuring consistency and enhancing user experience. Motta’s economic framework on vertical integration emphasizes that such agreements often foster innovation and efficiency, benefiting not only consumers but also device manufacturers, who reinvest their share of revenues into product development.
Moreover, no lock-in effect exists: consumers can easily switch default search engines, as demonstrated by the availability of competing search options like Bing and DuckDuckGo.
4. Dynamic Efficiency and Innovation Incentives
Professor Motta underscores the importance of dynamic efficiency in competition policy, particularly in markets driven by innovation. Google’s ad tech stack has enabled significant advancements in AI-driven ad placement and real-time bidding, generating higher revenues for publishers and better-targeted advertisements for users. Imposing structural remedies, such as forced unbundling, risks stifling this innovation, ultimately harming consumers and smaller advertisers.
5. Counterfactual Flaws in CMA’s Analysis
The CMA’s findings rest on speculative counterfactual scenarios that assume a perfectly competitive market absent Google’s practices. These scenarios fail to account for:
• The natural barriers to entry in digital markets, such as high fixed costs and network effects.
• The active competition from platforms like Meta, Amazon, and TikTok, which challenge Google’s dominance in specific niches.
Precedent from Verizon v. Trinko (2004) establishes that natural barriers and innovation-driven advantages do not constitute anticompetitive behavior. Without concrete evidence of foreclosure or harm to consumers, the CMA’s counterfactuals lack credibility.
6. The Risks of Overregulation
The CMA’s proposed remedies could have unintended negative consequences, including:
• Harming small publishers: By disrupting Google’s ad tech ecosystem, smaller publishers may lose access to efficient ad placement tools, reducing their revenue streams.
• Increasing consumer costs: If ad costs rise due to inefficiencies, this may translate into higher prices for goods and services.
• Stifling innovation: Restrictive interventions could deter investment in the UK’s tech sector, reducing its global competitiveness.
7. International Precedents and Policy Alignment
The CMA’s approach diverges from recent decisions by the French Competition Authority, which accepted behavioral remedies from Google to address competition concerns without resorting to drastic structural measures. Consistency across jurisdictions is crucial to maintaining a fair and predictable regulatory environment for global companies.
Conclusion and Request
In light of these arguments, I respectfully urge the CMA to reconsider its provisional findings and adopt a more nuanced, effects-based approach. Specifically, I recommend:
• Revisiting the reliance on narrow market definitions and market shares as indicators of dominance.
• Prioritizing consumer welfare and innovation in assessing potential remedies.
• Avoiding disproportionate interventions that risk harming competition, investment, and technological progress.
I remain available to provide further evidence or clarification to support this request.
Yours sincerely,
[Your Full Name]
[Your Contact Information]
This

======================
Your Law Firm’s Letterhead]
[Date]
To:
Competition and Markets Authority
The Cabot
25 Cabot Square
London E14 4QZ
Subject: Formal Complaint Challenging CMA’s Provisional Findings on Google’s Ad Tech Practices
Dear Sir/Madam,
We represent Google LLC and its subsidiaries (“Google”) in relation to the Competition and Markets Authority’s (“CMA”) provisional findings dated 6 September 2024, alleging anti-competitive conduct in Google’s ad tech operations. We submit this letter to formally contest the Statement of Objections, highlighting legal, factual, and procedural grounds, while underscoring the significant risks of negative externalities should the CMA pursue penalties or remedies based on these findings.
1. Legal and Factual Grounds to Challenge the CMA’s Decision
a. Market Definition and Dominance
The CMA’s narrow definition of the relevant market—“open-display ad tech”—artificially inflates Google’s dominance. The digital advertising market is highly dynamic, encompassing diverse platforms (e.g., Meta, Amazon, TikTok) and direct publisher-advertiser arrangements.
• Legal Precedent: In United Brands v. Commission (Case 27/76), the European Court of Justice emphasized that market definition must reflect economic realities. The CMA’s market framing disregards vibrant competition from multiple players, creating a flawed foundation for its findings.
b. Revenue-Sharing Agreements (RSAs)
The CMA’s characterization of RSAs as exclusionary fails to account for their pro-competitive benefits. RSAs provide mutual economic advantages for Google and its partners, enhancing consumer experiences through optimized ad placements and device affordability.
• Precedent: In Intel v. Commission (Case T-286/09), the General Court acknowledged that rebates and exclusivity agreements may have legitimate pro-competitive justifications. Similarly, Google’s RSAs foster innovation and market efficiencies.
c. Default Status and Consumer Choice
The CMA’s reliance on “default bias” overlooks evidence that consumers actively choose Google due to its superior search quality. Default settings do not foreclose competitors but reflect Google’s ability to meet user expectations better than rivals.
• Precedent: In United States v. Microsoft Corp. (2001), the court recognized that superior products can legitimately lead to market leadership. Default bias is not synonymous with coercion, and consumer choice remains paramount in Google’s success.
d. Economic and Technical Barriers Are Natural, Not Artificial
The CMA’s findings ignore the substantial investment required to replicate Google’s infrastructure, which represents a natural barrier, not an artificial one.
• Legal Insight: In Verizon v. Trinko (2004), the U.S. Supreme Court held that antitrust law does not obligate a dominant firm to lower natural barriers or aid competitors, especially in high-cost, innovation-driven markets like ad tech.
e. Absence of Demonstrable Consumer Harm
The CMA’s case lacks concrete evidence of consumer harm—a core requirement for antitrust violations. Instead, Google’s practices sustain free content for users and higher revenues for publishers, which benefit the broader digital economy.
2. Procedural and Evidentiary Concerns
a. Flawed Counterfactual Analysis
The CMA’s speculative counterfactuals fail to reflect real-world market dynamics. They underestimate competition from other platforms and misinterpret Google’s role in enhancing ad tech efficiency.
• Recommendation: A rigorous economic analysis should account for the competitive pressures from rivals such as Amazon and Meta, as well as the clear benefits to consumers and publishers.
b. Insufficient Evidence for Claims of Harm
The CMA has not established that Google’s RSAs or default search agreements have materially excluded rivals or harmed consumer welfare. Without such evidence, the findings lack the requisite legal and factual basis.
3. Risks of Overregulation and Negative Externalities
a. Impact on SMEs and Publishers
Structural remedies, such as forced unbundling, could disproportionately harm small publishers and advertisers by increasing their costs and operational complexity. These measures risk destabilizing the ecosystem that relies on Google’s tools for efficient ad placement.
b. Chilling Effect on Innovation
Aggressive enforcement could deter investment in the UK’s digital economy, discouraging innovation by both Google and its competitors.
• Precedent: In United States v. IBM (1969), the government recognized that overregulation in tech markets could stifle innovation, ultimately withdrawing its case to avoid such consequences.
c. International Policy Divergence
The CMA’s approach risks misalignment with the U.S. DOJ and EU investigations, potentially creating regulatory uncertainty that undermines the UK’s competitiveness as a tech hub.
4. Pro-Competitive Benefits of Google’s Practices
Google’s vertically integrated ad tech stack brings significant consumer and industry benefits:
• Enhanced Efficiency: Streamlined processes reduce transaction costs and improve ad relevance, maximizing publisher revenue and advertiser ROI.
• Innovation: Continuous advancements in AI-driven targeting benefit both advertisers and end-users.
• Support for Free Content: Ad revenues facilitated by Google sustain free or low-cost access to diverse digital content.
Conclusion and Recommendations
In light of the above, we urge the CMA to reconsider its provisional findings and adopt a more balanced approach that reflects the complexities of the ad tech market. We recommend:
• Revisiting the market definition to align with economic realities.
• Recognizing the pro-competitive justifications of RSAs and Google’s integrated stack.
• Exploring behavioral remedies, such as increased transparency in auction processes, instead of structural interventions that risk harming consumers and the digital economy.
We remain committed to engaging in further discussions and providing additional evidence to assist in a fair and proportionate resolution.
Yours faithfully,
[Your Full Name]
[Your Position]
[Your Contact Information]
[Your Law Firm’s Name]

=====================================================

3pint. application to CAT

The Registrar
Competition Appeal Tribunal
Salisbury Square House
8 Salisbury Square
London EC4Y 8AP

Re: Application for Permission to Intervene in Case Nos: 1572/7/7/22 & 1582/7/7/23

Dear Sir/Madam,

We write on behalf of the COCOO to seek permission under Rule 16 of the Competition Appeal Tribunal Rules 2015 to intervene in the collective proceedings brought by Ad Tech Collective Action LLP against Alphabet Inc. and its subsidiaries (Google).

1. Identity of The COCOO

The Competition & Consumer Organisation Party Limited (The COCOO). UK Companies House Registration Number: 15466919 Address: 23 Village Way, Beckenham. Postcode: BR33NA.United Kingdom. Email: contact@cocoo.uk Phone: 07716601277
Our constitutional mandate is to quality-control, ex-officio, decisions by competition authorities, public bodies or firms, that could deter synergies and positive externalities, or harm competition, investment, consumer welfare or the public interest
COCOO is uniquely positioned to offer insights into how these proceedings will impact competition, innovation, and market efficiency.

2. Title of the Proceedings

The present proceedings are titled:
• Case Nos: 1572/7/7/22 and 1582/7/7/23
• Parties: Ad Tech Collective Action LLP (Proposed Class Representative) v Alphabet Inc., Google LLC, Google Ireland Ltd., and Google UK Ltd.

3. Address for Service

COCOO designates [Your Legal Representative’s Name] of [Firm Name], [Address], as its representative for these proceedings.

4. Issues Affecting COCOO

The allegations against Google focus on self-preferencing and vertical integration in its ad tech stack, raising questions about competitive dynamics in this sector. These claims, if upheld, could have significant negative consequences for publishers, advertisers, and consumers by disrupting an ecosystem that relies on innovation, interoperability, and efficiency.

5. Position in Support of Google

COCOO supports Google’s position and will focus on the following:

Undermining Class Certification
• Key Argument: Emphasize the lack of concrete and robust counterfactual scenarios. Claimants must prove a common loss across the proposed class, but the dynamic nature of ad auctions and varied publisher practices undermine this assertion.
• Strengthening with UK Context: Highlight the challenges claimants face in certifying an opt-out class under the Consumer Rights Act 2015. The Tribunal should reject speculative economic models that lack real-world substantiation, as evident from prior UK cases like Merricks v Mastercard​​.
2. Challenging Market Definition and Dominance
• Key Argument: Argue that the claimants narrowly define the market as “open web display ads” to artificially inflate Google’s dominance.
• Strengthening with UK Context: Introduce evidence that UK publishers use a range of ad platforms (e.g., Meta, Amazon) in addition to Google, highlighting vibrant competition. Stress that applying a rigid market definition risks misaligning UK competition policy with global norms​​.
3. Pro-Competitive Justifications
• Key Argument: Google’s practices result in innovations that improve auction efficiency and generate higher revenues for publishers.
• Strengthening with UK Context: Reference the French Competition Authority’s decision where Google’s proposed commitments were seen as restoring competitive market functioning. Stress that applying similar remedies in the UK ensures consistency without undermining economic efficiency​​.
4. Attacking Methodology and Quantification of Damages
• Key Argument: Claimants rely on speculative damages models that do not account for real-world complexities in ad auctions.
• Strengthening with UK Context: Use expert evidence to show how UK publishers might have benefited from Google’s innovations, offsetting alleged losses. Highlight flaws in using aggregated models to infer damages for heterogeneous publishers​​.
5. Leveraging Google’s Previous Commitments and Compliance
• Key Argument: Google has demonstrated goodwill by adhering to commitments accepted by the French Competition Authority, improving interoperability and transparency.
• Strengthening with UK Context: Stress that imposing additional remedies in the UK risks overregulation and could harm small publishers by increasing operational complexity. Emphasize that Google’s ongoing commitments should suffice to address concerns without disrupting the market​​.
Broader Implications for UK Competition Policy and Economy
• Risk of Overregulation: Highlight that a decision against Google could embolden interventionist policies by the CMA, deterring foreign investment and innovation​.
• Economic Impact: Point out that structural remedies could disproportionately harm small UK publishers, reducing their competitiveness and threatening content diversity.

To develop a strategy for defending Google in these collective proceedings related to its alleged anticompetitive practices in ad tech, we need to focus on:
• Undermining the Class Certification: Emphasize the technical and legal deficiencies in the claimant’s methodology for proving class-wide harm, such as the lack of robust counterfactuals and reliance on speculative damages models​​​.
• Challenging Market Definition and Dominance: Argue that the market definitions provided by the claimants are overly narrow or artificial, thereby challenging the assertion of Google’s dominant position​​.
• Highlighting the Pro-Competitive Justifications: Stress that Google’s integration of its platforms, such as DFP and AdX, results in efficiency gains and better outcomes for publishers and advertisers​​.
• Attacking Methodology and Quantification of Damages: Criticize the claimant’s reliance on flawed economic models that lack real-world data and fail to properly estimate damages​​.
• Building on Previous Settlements and Compliance: Reference Google’s commitments in similar cases (e.g., the French Competition Authority) and highlight ongoing compliance efforts to show goodwill and mitigate allegations of willful misconduct​​.

(a) Economic Efficiency and Total Welfare (Motta’s Framework)
• Key Point: Motta’s framework highlights that competition policy should aim to maximize total welfare, considering both consumer and producer surplus.
• Defense Argument: Google’s vertically integrated ad tech stack reduces transaction costs, enhances real-time bidding, and ensures seamless ad delivery, which collectively boost efficiency and benefit publishers and advertisers. Unbundling these services would likely disrupt these efficiencies, leading to higher costs and reduced functionality for smaller players.
• Illustration: Use case studies demonstrating how SMEs benefit from Google’s integrated services, which they cannot replicate independently due to cost and complexity constraints.
(b) Dynamic Efficiency and Innovation Incentives
• Key Point: Dynamic efficiency drives long-term innovation and market competitiveness, an aspect crucial to the fast-evolving digital advertising sector.
• Defense Argument: Google’s integration fosters innovation in AI-powered ad optimization, benefiting both publishers and advertisers. Remedies like forced separation could stifle this innovation, harming the market in the long term.
• Illustration: Highlight Google’s innovations in targeting algorithms, which have increased ad relevance and consumer engagement, showing how these innovations would slow under restrictive remedies.
(c) Counterfactual Challenges and Methodological Flaws
• Key Point: Counterfactual analysis is vital in competition cases but must be robust and realistic.
• Defense Argument: The PCR’s counterfactuals assume an idealized, highly competitive market without substantiating how competition would naturally evolve without Google’s alleged abuses. They fail to account for network effects, economies of scale, and the competition from platforms like Meta and Amazon.
• Illustration: Use Motta’s analysis to critique these assumptions and provide alternative scenarios that reflect the complexities of digital markets.
(d) Two-Sided Market Dynamics and Consumer Welfare
• Key Point: Digital advertising markets are two-sided, where efficiencies for advertisers indirectly benefit consumers through free or lower-cost services.
• Defense Argument: Google’s ability to optimize ad delivery benefits consumers by supporting free platforms like YouTube and Search. Remedies disrupting this balance risk reducing consumer welfare through higher advertising costs and less innovation.
• Illustration: Present data showing how lower ad costs on Google’s platforms sustain free consumer services and incentivize content diversity.
Contribution to the Tribunal’s Deliberation
COCOO’s intervention will provide:
• Economic Analysis: Evidence-based assessments of vertical integration and its benefits.
• Critique of PCR’s Models: Addressing the speculative and flawed methodologies in the counterfactual scenarios and damages calculations.
• Policy Implications: Highlighting the risks of disproportionate remedies, such as overregulation, which could harm the UK’s digital economy and competitiveness.
Scope of Intervention
COCOO will focus on:
• Economic Impact: The effect of proposed remedies on market efficiency, especially for SMEs.
• Counterfactual Feasibility: Critiquing the PCR’s economic models and damages methodology.
• Policy Considerations: Balancing competition enforcement with the need for innovation and global competitiveness.

(a) Economic Efficiency and Total Welfare (Motta’s Framework)

Massimo Motta emphasizes that competition policy should maximize total welfare, balancing consumer and producer surplus. Google’s vertical integration generates significant efficiency gains by reducing transaction costs, enhancing real-time bidding, and facilitating seamless ad delivery. Remedies such as unbundling risk harming these efficiencies, which could reduce total welfare by increasing operational complexity and costs for smaller market players.

(b) Dynamic Efficiency and Innovation Incentives

Google’s integration of ad tech services fosters dynamic efficiency by enabling continuous innovation, particularly in AI-driven ad optimization. Motta highlights the risk of chilling effects on innovation when competition enforcement targets practices that enhance efficiency and benefit consumers. Disruptive remedies could slow innovation and harm both publishers and advertisers reliant on Google’s tools.

(c) Counterfactual Challenges and Methodological Flaws

The PCR’s claims rest on speculative counterfactual scenarios that assume a highly competitive market without Google’s alleged abuses. These counterfactuals fail to account for the complexity of digital advertising markets, including network effects, economies of scale, and competitive pressure from alternative platforms (e.g., Meta, Amazon). Motta’s work underscores the need for robust economic evidence when assessing counterfactuals, which is lacking in this case.

(d) Two-Sided Market Dynamics and Consumer Welfare

Digital advertising operates in a two-sided market, where efficiencies on the advertiser side indirectly benefit consumers through lower prices and free services (e.g., Google Search, YouTube). Remedies that undermine Google’s ability to optimize both sides of the market could lead to higher costs and reduced consumer welfare.

6. Contribution to the Tribunal’s Deliberation

COCOO’s intervention will assist the Tribunal by:

• Providing economic analysis of vertical integration benefits, drawing on Motta’s arguments to demonstrate how these efficiencies support publishers, advertisers, and consumers.
• Critiquing speculative counterfactuals and damages methodologies presented by the PCR, offering a grounded perspective on market realities.
• Assessing the proportionality of proposed remedies, advocating for less intrusive measures that preserve market efficiency while addressing competition concerns.

7. Scope of Intervention

COCOO will limit its intervention to the following areas:

• The economic impact of proposed remedies on market efficiency, particularly for SMEs.
• The adequacy and feasibility of the PCR’s counterfactual scenarios and damages analysis.
• Broader policy implications, including the risks of overregulation and reduced global competitiveness for the UK’s digital economy.

Conclusion

For the reasons outlined above, COCOO respectfully requests permission to intervene. Our unique perspective and expertise will provide valuable insights into the complexities of this case, supporting the Tribunal in its deliberation and contributing to a fair resolution.

We remain at the Tribunal’s disposal to provide further information or clarification.

Yours faithfully,

[Your Full Name]
[Your Position]

On behalf of COCOO

 


Your Law Firm’s Letterhead]
[Date]Antitrust Division
U.S. Department of Justice
950 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20530-0001Subject: Formal Complaint Challenging DOJ Decisions in Google Search and Ad Tech CasesDear

Sir/Madam,On behalf of [Your Organization], we are writing to formally challenge the Department of Justice’s decisions in two cases against Google: the Search case ruling of August 5, 2024, and the ongoing Ad Tech case. We believe these decisions are based on flawed economic analyses and may result in unintended negative consequences for the digital economy.

1. U.S. DOJ v. Google (Search)

Misapplication of Monopoly Standards

Judge Mehta’s ruling that Google illegally maintained a monopoly in online search fails to account for the dynamic nature of digital markets

1. The decision relies on outdated monopoly standards that are ill-suited to assess competition in rapidly evolving tech sectors.

Overlooking Consumer Choice

The ruling underestimates users’ ability to switch search engines easily. Google’s market position is primarily due to superior product quality and continuous innovation, not anticompetitive practices.

Potential Harm to Innovation

Enforcing this decision could stifle innovation and harm consumer welfare by discouraging companies from investing in product improvements that lead to market leadership.

2. U.S. DOJ v. Google (Ad Tech)

Mischaracterization of Market Dynamics

The DOJ’s case against Google’s ad tech practices mischaracterizes the competitive landscape. It fails to account for the presence of strong competitors like Amazon and Meta, which exert significant competitive pressure.

Pro-Competitive Benefits Ignored

The investigation overlooks the pro-competitive benefits of Google’s integrated ad tech stack, which enhances efficiency and reduces transaction costs for publishers and advertisers.

Risk of Overregulation

Aggressive enforcement in the ad tech sector could lead to market fragmentation, potentially increasing costs for small businesses and reducing the overall efficiency of the digital advertising ecosystem.

Yes, there are several legal precedents that could support a complaint against the DOJ’s decisions in the Google cases:

  1. Verizon v. Trinko (2004): This U.S. Supreme Court case established that antitrust law does not obligate a dominant firm to lower natural barriers or aid competitors, especially in high-cost, innovation-driven markets
    1

    . This precedent could be used to argue that Google’s market position is due to natural barriers and innovation, not anticompetitive practices.

  2. United States v. Microsoft Corp. (2001): The court recognized that superior products can legitimately lead to market leadership
    1

    . This could support the argument that Google’s success is due to the quality of its products rather than anticompetitive behavior.

  3. United Brands v. Commission (Case 27/76): The European Court of Justice emphasized that market definition must reflect economic realities
    1

    . This could be used to challenge the DOJ’s narrow market definition in the Google cases.

  4. Intel v. Commission (Case T-286/09): The General Court acknowledged that rebates and exclusivity agreements may have legitimate pro-competitive justifications
    1

    . This could support Google’s arguments regarding its revenue-sharing agreements.

  5. United States v. IBM (1969): In this case, the government recognized that overregulation in tech markets could stifle innovation and ultimately withdrew its case
    1

    . This precedent could be used to argue against aggressive enforcement that might deter investment and innovation in the digital economy.

These precedents could be used to challenge the DOJ’s findings, arguing that they fail to account for the dynamic nature of digital markets, overlook pro-competitive justifications, and risk stifling innovation through overregulation

Recommendations

We urge the DOJ to reconsider its approach in both cases:

  1. Adopt a more nuanced, effects-based analysis that considers the realities of digital markets.
  2. Recognize the role of innovation and quality in shaping market dynamics.
  3. Consider the potential negative impacts of overly aggressive enforcement on the broader digital economy.

We remain available to provide further information or clarification on these matters.Sincerely,[Your Name]
[Your Title]
[Your Organization]


Based on the provided search results and the context of the US DOJ v Google (Ad Tech) case, here are the key arguments to include when challenging the DOJ’s findings:

Mischaracterization of Market Dynamics

The DOJ’s case against Google’s ad tech practices fails to accurately represent the competitive landscape. It does not adequately account for strong competitors like Amazon and Meta, which exert significant competitive pressure in the digital advertising market

1

.

Pro-Competitive Benefits Overlooked

The investigation does not sufficiently consider the pro-competitive benefits of Google’s integrated ad tech stack. This integration enhances efficiency and reduces transaction costs for publishers and advertisers, ultimately benefiting the entire ecosystem

1

.

Flawed Market Definition

Challenge the narrow market definition used by the DOJ. Argue that the digital advertising market is highly dynamic and encompasses diverse platforms and direct publisher-advertiser arrangements. A more comprehensive market definition would provide a more accurate representation of Google’s position

1

.

Absence of Consumer Harm

Emphasize the lack of concrete evidence demonstrating harm to consumers – a core requirement for antitrust violations. Google’s practices support free content for users and higher revenues for publishers, benefiting the broader digital economy

1

.

Innovation and Efficiency

Highlight Google’s role in driving innovation in the ad tech sector, including advancements in AI-driven ad placement and real-time bidding. These innovations generate higher revenues for publishers and better-targeted advertisements for users

1

.

Risk of Overregulation

Argue that aggressive enforcement in the ad tech sector could lead to market fragmentation, potentially increasing costs for small businesses and reducing the overall efficiency of the digital advertising ecosystem

1

.

Natural Market Barriers

Emphasize that any barriers to entry in digital markets, such as high fixed costs and network effects, are natural rather than artificially created by Google. Cite the Verizon v. Trinko (2004) precedent, which establishes that natural barriers and innovation-driven advantages do not constitute anticompetitive behavior

1

.

Effects-Based Analysis

Advocate for an effects-based analysis that evaluates actual harm to consumers and competitors, rather than relying solely on market shares or theoretical models. This approach would provide a more accurate assessment of Google’s impact on the market

1

.—————

The potential long-term effects on the tech industry if Google is forced to change its practices could be significant and far-reaching:

Innovation and Investment

  • Chilling effect on innovation in the ad tech sector, as companies may become hesitant to develop integrated solutions
    1
  • Reduced investment in R&D across the tech industry due to fears of regulatory scrutiny
    1

Market Structure

  • Fragmentation of the ad tech ecosystem, potentially leading to increased costs and reduced efficiency for advertisers and publishers
    1
  • Emergence of new players in the digital advertising space, possibly leading to a more diverse but less integrated market
    1

Consumer Experience

  • Potential reduction in the quality and relevance of online advertisements, affecting user experience
    1
  • Possible increase in costs for digital services that are currently free, as companies seek alternative revenue streams
    1

Competition Dynamics

  • Shift in competitive landscape, with smaller players potentially gaining market share
    1
  • Increased scrutiny on other large tech companies, potentially leading to a more cautious approach to product integration and expansion
    1

Global Tech Leadership

  • Risk of undermining the UK’s competitiveness as a tech hub due to regulatory uncertainty
    1
  • Potential misalignment with global tech policies, creating challenges for international companies operating in the UK market
    1

These effects could reshape the tech industry’s approach to innovation, market strategy, and user engagement, potentially altering the trajectory of digital advertising and related technologies for years to come


The potential consequences for consumers if Google is restricted by the DOJ’s decisions could be significant:

Reduced Quality of Search and Ad Services

  • Consumers may experience less relevant search results and advertisements if Google’s ability to use integrated data across its services is limited.
  • The quality of free services like Google Search could decline if Google’s revenue from advertising is significantly impacted.

Potential Increase in Costs

  • Some digital services that are currently free might start charging fees if Google’s ad revenue model is disrupted.
  • Advertisers may face higher costs, which could be passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices for goods and services.

Less Innovation

  • Restrictions on Google’s practices could lead to reduced investment in research and development, potentially slowing down innovations that benefit consumers.
  • The chilling effect on innovation could extend beyond Google, affecting the broader tech industry’s willingness to develop new consumer-friendly products and services.

Fragmented User Experience

  • If Google is forced to unbundle its services, consumers might face a more fragmented digital experience, requiring them to use multiple platforms for tasks currently integrated within Google’s ecosystem.

Reduced Access to Free Content

  • Publishers relying on Google’s ad tech might struggle to monetize their content effectively, potentially leading to less free content available online for consumers.

Privacy and Data Security Concerns

  • Changes to Google’s data practices could have unintended consequences for user privacy and data security, depending on how new regulations are implemented.

While these potential consequences are significant, it’s important to note that the actual impact on consumers would depend on the specific restrictions imposed and how the market adapts to these changes


The potential long-term effects on consumer prices if Google is restricted could be significant:

  1. Increased advertising costs: If Google’s ad tech practices are disrupted, it may lead to less efficient ad placement and targeting. This could result in higher costs for advertisers, which may be passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices for goods and services
    1

    .

  2. Reduced free content: Publishers relying on Google’s ad tech might struggle to monetize their content effectively. This could lead to less free content available online, with some publishers potentially moving to subscription models or paywalls
    1

    .

  3. Potential fees for currently free services: Some digital services that are currently free might start charging fees if Google’s ad revenue model is significantly impacted. This could directly increase costs for consumers who previously enjoyed these services at no charge
    1

    .

  4. Higher prices due to reduced competition: If Google’s restrictions lead to a less competitive ad tech market, it could result in higher advertising costs across the board. These increased costs could be reflected in higher consumer prices for various products and services advertised online
    1

    .

  5. Indirect price increases: The chilling effect on innovation in the tech industry could lead to fewer efficiency gains and cost reductions being passed on to consumers over time, indirectly contributing to higher prices
    1

    .

It’s important to note that these effects are potential outcomes and would depend on the specific restrictions imposed on Google and how the market adapts to these changes.

——–

The potential economic impacts on publishers if Google’s ad tech practices are changed could be significant:

  1. Reduced revenue: Publishers may experience lower ad revenues due to less efficient ad placement and targeting mechanisms
    1

    .

  2. Increased operational costs: Publishers might face higher operational complexity and costs if forced to use multiple ad tech platforms instead of Google’s integrated stack
    1

    .

  3. Disruption of free content model: Smaller publishers could struggle to monetize their content effectively, potentially leading to a reduction in free online content available to consumers
    1

    .

  4. Market fragmentation: The ad tech ecosystem could become more fragmented, potentially increasing transaction costs and reducing overall efficiency for publishers
    1

    .

  5. Innovation slowdown: Changes to Google’s practices might lead to reduced investment in ad tech innovation, potentially slowing down advancements that benefit publishers
    1

    .

  6. Competitive disadvantage: Smaller publishers may be disproportionately affected, as they often rely more heavily on Google’s tools for efficient ad placement
    1

    .

These impacts could significantly alter the digital publishing landscape, potentially leading to consolidation in the industry and changes in how online content is monetized and distributed.


Changes in Google’s ad tech practices could significantly influence innovation in the publishing industry:

  1. Reduced R&D Investment: If Google’s ad tech revenues decrease, it may lead to reduced investment in ad tech innovation, potentially slowing down advancements that benefit publishers
    1

    .

  2. Fragmentation of Ad Tech: Disruption of Google’s integrated ad stack could lead to a more fragmented ecosystem, potentially increasing complexity and costs for publishers to manage multiple platforms
    1

    .

  3. Efficiency Impact: Changes to Google’s practices might reduce the efficiency of ad placement and targeting, potentially affecting publishers’ ability to monetize content effectively
    1

    .

  4. Shift in Innovation Focus: Publishers may need to innovate in alternative monetization strategies if ad revenues decline, potentially leading to new subscription models or content formats
    1

    .

  5. Data Utilization: Restrictions on data usage across services could impact publishers’ ability to leverage user insights for content personalization and ad targeting
    1

    .

  6. New Market Entrants: Changes in the ad tech landscape could create opportunities for new players to enter the market, potentially spurring innovation in niche areas of digital advertising
    1

    .

These potential changes could reshape the publishing industry’s approach to content monetization and distribution, influencing the direction of innovation in response to a shifting ad tech ecosystem

Posted by wpMY0dxsz043 in COCOO CASES, 0 comments