MLEX.CASEFILE The EU case file number is M.11625
Křetínský’s EP Group seeks EU approval to buy Royal Mail owner
MLEX.CASEFILE The EU case file number is M.11625
Křetínský’s EP Group seeks EU approval to buy Royal Mail owner
The buyout of International Distribution Services appears more likely to gain national security approval in the UK, after the business minister (sosbt) described the Czech investor seeking to buy the Royal Mail owner as a “legitimate business figure.”
Daniel Křetínský’s bid through EP UK is undergoing a national security probe, including scrutiny of any potential links to Russia, following his 3.6 billion-pound ($4.6 billion) cash offer for the company in May (see here).
Křetínský’s investment vehicle, Vesa Equity, already owns about 27.6 percent of IDS and the holding was reviewed on national security grounds and cleared in 2022.
Business minister Jonathan Reynolds yesterday rebuffed a question regarding business dealings with Russia from a member of a Parliamentary committee in London.
“Mr Křetínský is of course the principal shareholder in Royal Mail and has already been through a National Security and Investment Act process. I would simply say if there were anything of the like that you describe in terms of links to Russia, I would have hoped that wouldn’t have resulted in him becoming the principal shareholder,” Reynolds told the committee.
“He is a legitimate business figure who has a number of business interests in Europe and the UK,” Reynolds said.
The national security review is being undertaken by the Cabinet Office, and Reynolds said he couldn’t comment on the timing of a decision.
Křetínský’s other UK investments include stakes in West Ham United Football Club and supermarket chain J. Sainsbury.
IDS, which owns international parcels network GLS and the postal service, last month accepted a 3.6 billion-pound ($4.6 billion) cash offer from EP UK, controlled by businessman and lawyer Křetínský. The buyout of Britain’s 500-year-old postal service will need national securities clearance and antitrust approvals in several countries (see here). The comments in the manifesto follow pressure from Communication Workers Union general secretary Dave Ward for changes to the company structure, in response to the deal. The CWU, which is affiliated to Labour, said last month it would ask the party for “a new model of ownership for Royal Mail,” in which its members and customers have a “direct say in key decisions.”…..The CWU also urged Labour to consider creating a “golden share” for the Royal Mail, which would entitle the holder to special rights over other investors, to protect the national infrastructure.
EP will offer to continue to provide a universal “one-price-goes-anywhere postal service, keep Royal Mail’s head office and tax residency in the UK, and provide labor union recognition, IDS said. However, these undertakings are only for five years after the completion of the deal, which the company expects in the first quarter of 2025….Jonathan Reynolds, the business secretary for the Labour Party — which is forecast to win the UK general election next month — said that he welcomed the assurances provided by Křetínský, Reuters reported…..Křetínský’s investment vehicle, Vesa Equity, already owns 27.6 percent of IDS. The holding was called in for a full national security assessment in 2022, but the government decided that no action was necessary. His other UK investments include stakes in West Ham United Football Club and supermarket chain J. Sainsbury
November 28, 2024, 08:46 GMT | Official Statement) — MLex Summary: Parties interested in plans by Nvidia to take over Israeli startup Run:ai now have ten days to share their feedback with the European Commission. The EU merger regulator has set a provisional Dec. 20 deadline to decide on the transaction.
****************************************
Notice follows.
C/2024/7203
28.11.2024
Prior notification of a concentration
(Case M.11766 – NVIDIA / RUN:AI)
(Text with EEA relevance)
(C/2024/7203)
1. On 15 November 2024, the Commission received notification of a proposed concentration pursuant to Article 4 of Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 (1).
This notification concerns the following undertakings:
—NVIDIA Corporation (‘NVIDIA’, United States of America),
—Run:ai Labs Ltd (‘Run:ai’, Israel).
NVIDIA will acquire within the meaning of Article 3(1)(b) of the Merger Regulation control of the whole of Run:ai.
The concentration is accomplished by way of purchase of shares.
The concentration has been referred to the Commission by the Italian Competition Authority pursuant to Article 22(3) of the Merger Regulation.
2. The business activities of the undertakings concerned are the following:
—NVIDIA designs and supplies accelerated computing platforms including Graphics Processing Units for gaming, datacenters, professional visualization, and automotive applications. NVIDIA also supplies network interconnect products and solutions,
—Run:ai develops software that helps customers schedule workloads on clusters of datacenter GPUs.
3. On preliminary examination, the Commission finds that the notified transaction could fall within the scope of the Merger Regulation. However, the final decision on this point is reserved.
4. The Commission invites interested third parties to submit their possible observations on the proposed operation to the Commission.
Observations must reach the Commission not later than 10 days following the date of this publication. The following reference should always be specified:
M.11766 – NVIDIA / RUN:AI
Observations can be sent to the Commission by email or by post. Please use the contact details below:
Email: COMP-MERGER-REGISTRY@ec.europa.eu
Postal address:
European Commission
Directorate-General for Competition
Merger Registry
1049 Bruxelles/Brussel
BELGIQUE/BELGIË
(1) OJ L 24, 29.1.2004, p. 1 (the ‘Merger Regulation’).
ELI: http://data.europa.eu/eli/C/2024/7203/oj
ISSN 1977-091X (electronic edition)
Administrators for Phones4U are awaiting the next round of their fight in the UK courts over allegations that the company was the victim of a deliberate, orchestrated attempt by the companies behind the EE, O2 and Vodafone mobile networks to put the chain out of business.
Speaking on a BBC Radio program today about the demise of Phones4U in 2014, John Caudwell said: “I have no doubt whatsoever that, in my mind, there was collusion, and there is very specific reason for that.”
“When Vodafone pulled out, that left the marketplace entirely to EE. EE could have easily then done an entirely different deal with Phones4U … and made a fortune out of Vodafone’s misfortune. And yet they didn’t. They pulled the plug as well. In my opinion, that was commercially stupid to the extreme degree — unless it was collusion.”
EE didn’t immediately respond to a request to comment on the remarks by Caudwell, who sold the Caudwell Group, which included Phones4U, to private equity in 2006.
All the mobile networks involved in the dispute have said they didn’t act unlawfully, that they made their decisions to end contracts with Phones4U for commercial reasons, and that their decisions were made independently of one another.
The High Court heard the damages action brought by Phones4U’s administrators in 2022, and in November last year it ruled that the mobile network operators hadn’t broken EU or UK competition law in their dealings with the retailer (see here).
Phones4U’s administrators asked the High Court for permission to appeal, but it refused (see here). They then went directly to the higher Court of Appeal, and in March this year they won their bid for leave to appeal (see here).
The Court of Appeal is now due to hear the substantive appeal next May. The UK antitrust regulator, the Competition and Markets Authority, has said it will intervene in Phones4U’s challenge.
— Claim and two rulings —
In the early 2010s, Phones4U was jostling with Carphone Warehouse as the UK’s best-known retailer of phone contracts for the major networks. It ended up collapsing after it lost major distribution contracts.
In 2018, Phones4U’s administrators filed a lawsuit claiming that its demise as a major mobile phone retailer in the UK, with numerous stores and service contracts, was the result of collusion among telecom operators that had collectively decided to terminate their agreements with the company.
They denied the allegations, and said they had made unilateral decisions to end dealings with Phones4U. They argued that its woes were down to its own management failings.
Among its court arguments, Phones4U said the court had applied wrong analysis to a hotel lunch meeting in 2012 between Olaf Swantee, who ran EE from 2011 to 2016, and Ronan Dunne, who led Telefónica’s O2 from 2008 to 2016. According to Phones4U, Dunne employed a pricing strategy in the telecom market that had a collusive effect.
In the High Court ruling, however, Judge Peter Roth said that “none of the defendants was in breach of either UK or EU competition law.” Further, he added that if O2 and EE had infringed competition law via a discussion between two executives in 2012, “that infringement did not affect the conduct of either O2 or EE as regards Phones4U.”
Roth did say that some “very senior executives … paid scant regard” to some recommended precautions around interacting with competitors. But, he said, it was “wrong to say that the evidence showed a general culture among the defendants of disregard for the requirements of competition law.”
The appeal case reference is CA-2024-000204 Phones 4U Limited (in Administration) v EE Limited and others.
Please email editors@mlex.com
The regulator is understood to be planning an appeal to the EU’s Court of Justice to contest the earlier ruling.
The EU’s lower-tier General Court annulled the original fine that was levied on Google for abusing its market power through the AdSense advertising service.
Google’s AdSense for Search platform included restrictive contracts with intermediaries that allowed Google to reserve premium space for its own adverts, and to veto ads from other providers, the commission concluded.
But, in September, EU judges ruled investigators had failed to properly assess the clauses in Google’s contracts that were allegedly abusive, including whether the clauses actually locked-in the tech giant’s customers.
“The European Commission has not demonstrated that the clauses in question had been capable of deterring publishers from sourcing from Google’s competing intermediaries,” the court said at the time.
While judges sided with the commission on most of its findings, they homed in on an error in assessing the duration of the contract clauses under scrutiny and the section of the market covered for the year 2016.
So, judges annulled the regulator’s decision because the clauses were not sufficiently identified as individual antitrust abuses.
An appeal is possible on points of law — rather than a full re-hearing of the facts of the case — to the EU’s Court of Justice.
The General Court case number was T-334/19.
Please email editors@mlex.com
November 29, 2024, 10:18 GMT | Insight) — ABC Technologies’ buyout of British automotive components company TI Fluid Systems is conditional on antitrust clearance in several countries including the UK, the EU and the US, in addition to foreign direct investment approvals.
The Canadian company, which is owned by Apollo Global Management, today agreed to buy TI Fluids for about 1 billion pounds ($1.3 billion) in cash.
The merger will need antitrust approval in Brazil, Canada, China, the EU, Japan, Mexico, Morocco, South Africa, South Korea, Turkey, the UK and the US. Foreign direct investment clearance will be required in Czechia, France, Germany, Italy and Spain, as well as EU foreign subsidies clearance.
“The acquisition by ABC Technologies brings together two strategically complementary businesses, creating a unique opportunity to significantly accelerate TI Fluid Systems’ strategic development,” said Tim Cobbold, the Chair of TI Fluid Systems.
TI Fluid Systems designs and makes fluid storage, carrying and delivery systems, as well as thermal management products and systems for petrol, electric and hybrid vehicles, and operates across 27 countries. ABC Technologies makes plastic parts for the global automotive industry.
TI Fluid Systems traded at 192.5 pence in London, approaching the 200 pence-a-share offer price.
The buyout is expected to complete in the first half of 2025, according to the statement.
Please email editors@mlex.com
COUNTERVAILING FACTORS: are there any countervailing factors that prevent or mitigate any SLC arising from the Merger?:
There are two main ways in which this could happen:
(a) Entry and/or expansion: the effect of a merger on competition may be
mitigated if effective entry and/or expansion by third parties occurs as a result
of the merger and any consequent adverse effect (eg a price rise).481
(b) Merger efficiencies: rivalry-enhancing efficiencies – ie efficiencies that
change the incentives of the merger firms and induce them to act as stronger
competitors to their rivals – may prevent an SLC by offsetting any
anticompetitive effects of a merger
7.3 This Chapter therefore assesses the potential for entry and/or expansion and
merger efficiencies to mitigate the loss of competitive constraint resulting from the
Merger
Entry and/or expansion
7.4 In this Chapter, we consider the possibility of entry into the relevant market by a
new market entrant, triggered by the Merger, and whether this would replace the
constraint eliminated by the Merger and therefore would constitute a countervailing
factor to prevent or mitigate any SLC arising from the Merger.483 This assessment
is distinct from our assessment set out in Chapter 5, Counterfactual, where we
have considered the scenario, in the absence of the Merger, in which a potential
purchaser may have acquired Sporting Index or its assets.
Framework of assessment
7.5 If effective entry and/or expansion occurs as a result of the merger and any
consequent adverse effect (for example, a price rise), the effect of the merger on
competition may be mitigated. In these situations, the CMA might conclude that no
SLC arises as a result of the merger
As set out in Chapter 6, Horizontal Unilateral Effects, our view is that there are
primarily three relevant parameters of competition in the supply of licensed online
sports spread betting in the UK:
(a) price;
(b) range of ‘spread markets’, and
(c) customer experience
we conclude that obtaining an FCA
licence would not be a lengthy and/or costly process. We understand that it would
take 6–12 months and that this would not be a costly process on its own, with an
approximate cost of just £10,000.
7.28 We note the third-party evidence that obtaining an FCA licence is a significant
barrier to entry. However, we also note that the third party considered that this
barrier could be overcome, and that it considered obtaining a licence to be a less
onerous process than it had initially thought.506
7.29 We therefore consider that the costs and timescales involved in obtaining the
required regulatory licence from the FCA do not represent a significant barrier to
entry on their own, and firms that already hold this licence (such as financial
leveraged trading providers) would not face this barrier at all. However, we note
that there are other barriers which an entrant would need to overcome, including
the costs required to comply with the FCA’s regulatory requirements on an
ongoing basis, which are considered in more detail below
Our view is that in order for a competitor to exert an effective competitive
constraint on the Merged Entity in the supply of licensed online sports spread
betting services in the UK, it would require the technology to:
(a) comply with the FCA’s regulated requirements; and
(b) offer spread betting prices in a manner that is sufficiently comprehensive to
compete with the Merged Entity.
A new entrant would need to offer services comparable to those of Sporting Index
pre-Merger to prevent an SLC arising from the Merger.
7.39 In our view, a financial leveraged trading provider looking to start supplying sports
spread betting in the UK would need to incur significant investment to acquire, and
in addition over multiple years to develop, the technology required to provide
sports specific spread betting services. This would include costs to:
(a) either acquire third-party sports data feeds or develop these sports data
feeds in-house; and
(b) adjust the spread betting technology it has such that it can use this data feed
to provide sports-specific spread betting prices.
7.40 While financial leveraged trading providers may be better placed than other
providers to develop this technology due to the general spread betting overlaps
between the platforms it already owns and the platform required to generate sports
spread betting prices, the evidence is that an investment of at least several
millions over multiple years would still be required in order to provide a sports
spread betting service comparable to that of Sporting Index pre-Merger.519
7.41 In our view, a sports fixed odds betting provider would also need to incur
significant investment over multiple years to provide licensed online sports spread
betting services in the UK, in order to:
(a) adjust its existing technology such that this is compliant with the FCA’s
regulatory requirements; and
(b) develop or acquire a platform that can generate spread betting prices.520
7.42 On the basis of the evidence, hiring the relevant IT staff to make these changes
would require an investment of at least several millions of pounds over multiple
years.
7.43 We also consider that after the initial upfront technological investment required for
a new entrant to start supplying sports spread betting services in the UK
comparable to those of Sporting Index pre-Merger, both sports fixed odds betting
providers and financial leveraged trading providers would then need to incur costs
on an ongoing basis to develop this technology in order to ensure that it is:
(a) an effective competitor to Spreadex’s sports spread betting services; and
(b) compliant on an ongoing basis with the FCA’s regulatory requirements.
7.44 We note that both sports fixed odds betting providers and financial leveraged
trading providers may be able to enter in a more timely manner than other entrants
should it be possible to procure from a third party the technology platform required
to provide sports spread betting services, rather than developing this technology
in-house. However, the evidence is mixed on whether there is any third-party
technology which can provide a similar level of service to that of Sporting Index
pre-Merger, and one third party told us that acquiring this technology would incur a
significant cost.521
7.45 The evidence provided to us therefore implies that any new entrant or rival looking
to expand into sports spread betting will face substantial upfront costs to
developing the required technology, as well as multiple years of investment before
any return on investment is realised. For example, we note Spreadex’s
assessment that a new entrant would require technological investment in excess
of £20 million over three years to provide a service comparable to that of Sporting
Index pre-Merger. Our view is that this required investment is large when
compared to the available profits, noting in particular that licensed online sports
spread betting had a market size of £[] million in 2022 and £[] million in 2023
(see paragraph 2.12).522
7.46 We therefore conclude that, relative to the size of the licensed online sports
spread betting market in the UK, the costs and timescales to develop and/or
acquire the required technology to provide a licensed online sports spread betting
service in the UK that is compliant with the FCA’s regulatory requirements and
sufficiently comprehensive to exert an effective competitive constraint on the
Merged Entity represents a significant barrier, making entry unlikely. If new entry
were to occur as a result of the Merger, we conclude that the technological
barriers mean that it would not be timely or of sufficient scale to prevent the SLC
identified in Chapter 6, Horizontal Unilateral Effects. Although we consider that
barriers to expansion are lower than barriers to entry as regards technology, they
are not relevant in this case since, following the Merger, there are no other
providers of licensed online sports spread betting services in the UK.
we provisionally concluded that, relative to the size of
the licensed online sports spread betting market in the UK, the costs and
timescales to develop and/or acquire the required industry expertise to provide a
licensed online sports spread betting service that is compliant with the FCA’s
regulatory requirements and is sufficiently comprehensive to exert an effective
competitive constraint on the Merged Entity represents a significant barrier to
entry.
7.58 Following our Provisional Findings, and in the course of our evidence gathering in
relation to possible remedies for the SLC provisionally identified, we received the
we conclude that, while staff and
expertise are important to the operation of a successful sports spread betting
business, and some investment may be required in order to ensure that a
business has the required staff, the costs and timescales to develop and/or
acquire the relevant industry expertise do not represent a significant barrier to
entry. We also note that firms already active in the wider betting industry are likely
to have existing staff with relevant transferable skills.
Conclusion on potential barriers to entry and/or expansion
7.60 Based on our assessment set out above, we conclude that while there are no
absolute impediments to entry into the market for licensed online sports spread
betting in the UK, the cost and timescales involved in developing and/or acquiring
the required technology, relative to the modest market opportunity available,
constitute a barrier to entry.
7.61 However, we conclude that the costs and timescales involved in obtaining the
required regulatory licence from the FCA do not represent a significant barrier to
entry on their own, and firms that already hold this licence (such as financial
spread betting providers) would not face this barrier at all.
7.62 We also conclude that the costs and timescales involved in obtaining the required
industry expertise do not represent a significant barrier to entry on their own, and
that firms already active in the wider betting industry are likely to have existing
staff with relevant transferable skills.
we conclude that entry and/or expansion would not be timely, likely and sufficient
to prevent an SLC arising from the Merger.
Efficiencies
7.71 We also consider whether there are any efficiencies arising from the Merger which
could be considered a potential countervailing factor to an SLC arising from the
Merger. The details of our assessment are set out below.
Framework for assessment
7.72 Efficiencies arising from a merger can enhance rivalry with the result that a merger
does not give rise to an SLC. In order for that to be the case, the efficiencies must:
(a) enhance rivalry in the supply of those products where an SLC may otherwise
arise;
(b) be timely, likely and sufficient to prevent an SLC from arising;
(c) be merger-specific; and
(d) benefit customers in the UK.
The MAGs state that merger firms who wish to make efficiency claims are
encouraged to provide verifiable evidence to support their claims in line with the
CMA’s framework.545 The MAGs note that it is for the merger firms to demonstrate
that the merger will result in efficiencies and the CMA must be satisfied that the
evidence shows that the above criteria are met
Our view is that the efficiency arguments submitted by Spreadex to date do not
meet the above criteria for the following reasons:
(a) The claimed efficiencies are not merger-specific, as the customer benefits
described above would have been available to Sporting Index customers had
they switched to Spreadex and this option would have existed with or without
the Merger.
(b) The claimed efficiencies also do not enhance rivalry in the market for
licensed online sports spread betting in the UK, given that the Merger has
resulted in Spreadex acquiring the only other licensed sports spread betting
provider in the UK, and the lack of any other effective competitive constraint
on the Merged Entity.
Conclusion on efficiencies as a countervailing factor
7.77 Based on our assessment above and in light of the evidence provided to us, we
conclude that the claimed efficiencies would not be merger specific or enhance
rivalry in the UK licensed online sports spread betting market, such as to prevent
an SLC arising from the Merger.
Conclusion on countervailing factors
7.78 Based on our assessment set out in this Chapter, it is our conclusion that there are
no countervailing factors to prevent or mitigate an SLC arising from the Merger.
we conclude that:
(a) the completed acquisition of Sporting Index by Spreadex has resulted in the
creation of an RMS; and
(b) the creation of that RMS has resulted, or may be expected to result, in an
SLC in the supply of licensed online sports spread betting services in the UK
it’s for the merger firms to demonstrate that the merger will result in efficiencies and the CMA must be
satisfied that the evidence shows that the above criteria are met.
Parties’ and third party views
The Parties submitted that they will be able to offer HAS-Vent customers a broader product range and []. Lindab customers will be offered flat, oval and Colourduct products, not currently offered by Lindab Limited and customers in Liverpool and Eastbourne will be able to more easily access Lindab products as
Lindab does not currently have any branches in these locations. Further, the
Parties submitted that economies of scale in purchasing are anticipated, which can
be passed on to customers.378
8.77 In response to a request from us to quantify any synergies or cost/quality benefits,
Lindab submitted that it hoped that additional volume discounts from third party
suppliers will enable joint sourcing at an overall lower cost which would assist in
offering competitive prices/discounts to customers. Furthermore, Lindab stated
that HAS-Vent will have access to [].379
8.78 In response to the same request, HAS-Vent stated that a number of synergies are
envisaged, including: (i) enabling HAS Vent’s access to [], and (ii) benefits from
the purchasing of [] and economies of scale when group purchasing, which in
turn, HAS-Vent believes will enable it to offer a more competitive offering to the
market.380
8.79 On the impact of the Merger, one third party stated that the Merged Entity would
have access to preferential input prices and, in turn, this could mean lower product
prices
Our assessment
8.80 The Parties have not substantiated their efficiency claims with any evidence in
order for us to assess the impact of any efficiencies arising from the Merger,
including whether such efficiencies enhance rivalry in the market for the supply of
circular ducts and fittings, or whether they qualify as relevant customer benefits
under the Act, and are likely to be passed onto customers.
8.81 We therefore consider that the merger efficiencies submitted by Lindab would not
be timely, likely, and sufficient to mitigate or prevent an SLC from arising in the
market for the supply of circular ducts and fittings.
Conclusion on countervailing factors
8.82 Based on the assessment set out in this chapter, we conclude that there are no
countervailing factors arising from entry and/or expansion or Merger efficiencies
that could offset the anti-competitive effects of the Merger and prevent the SLCs
which we have identified from arising.
CONCLUSION
9.1 As a result of our assessment, we have concluded that:
(a) the completed acquisition by Lindab of HAS-Vent has resulted in the creation
of an RMS; and
(b) the creation of that RMS has resulted, or may be expected to result, in an
SLC in the supply of circular ducts and fittings in the local areas centred
around Nottingham and Stoke-on-Trent.
We have concluded the Parties are close competitors in areas where the location
of the Parties’ branches means that they are both competing to supply customers
within the local area. We also found that the Merged Entity’s branches in
Nottingham and Stoke-on-Trent would not be sufficiently constrained by alternative
suppliers, either individually or in aggregate, as to prevent competition concerns
from arising. …… Accordingly, we concluded that the Merger has resulted or may be expected to
result in an SLC in the supply of circular ducts and fittings in the local areas
centred around: (i) Nottingham, and (ii) Stoke-on-Trent (the SLC Areas).
REMEDIES
As set out in our Merger Remedies Guidance, the CMA prefers structural remedies, such as divestiture or prohibition, over behavioural remedies, because:
(a) structural remedies are more likely to deal with an SLC and its resulting adverse effects directly and comprehensively at source by restoring rivalry;
(b) behavioural remedies are less likely to have an effective impact on the SLC and its resulting adverse effects, and are more likely to create significant costly distortions in market outcomes; and
(c) structural remedies rarely require monitoring and enforcement once implemented.
In the Remedies Notice, we set out the following remedy options:
(a) divestiture of one of the Parties’ sites in each of the SLC Areas;
(b) in the event that remedy (a) is found not to be effective, divestiture of the entire HAS-Vent business;
(c) behavioural remedies; and
(d) any other practicable remedy that could be effective in comprehensively addressing the SLCs.392
In the Remedies Notice, we set out our initial view that a behavioural remedy was
very unlikely to be an effective remedy. Since then, neither the Parties nor third
parties that engaged with us on remedies told us that we should be considering a
behavioural remedy, and we have also not received any evidence to suggest that
we should be considering any other type of remedy.
Accordingly, we focus the remainder of this chapter on assessing the effectiveness
of the following structural remedy options:
(a) divestiture of one of the Parties’ sites in each of the SLC Areas; and
(b) divestiture of the entire HAS-Vent business.
There are three broad categories of risks that may impair the effectiveness of a
divestiture remedy:
(a) Composition risks: these are risks that the scope of the divestiture package may be too constrained or not appropriately configured to attract a suitable purchaser or may not allow a purchaser to operate as an effective competitor in the market.
(b) Purchaser risks: these are risks that a suitable purchaser is not available or that the merger parties will dispose to a weak or otherwise inappropriate purchaser.
(c) Asset risks: these are risks that the competitive capability of a divestiture package will deteriorate before completion of the divestiture, for example, through the loss of customers or key members of staff.
An effective divestiture remedy must give us sufficient confidence that these
practical risks can be properly addressed. We therefore consider the following
issues: (i) the scope of the divestiture package; and (ii) the availability and
suitability of potential purchasers. As noted above, we consider how to ensure an
effective divestiture process after our assessment of the proportionality of the
remedies which we consider to be effective.
10.24 In considering the appropriate scope for a divestiture package, we should ensure
that it
(a) is sufficiently broad in scope to address all aspects of the SLC(s) and
resulting adverse effects;
(b) would enable the eventual purchaser to operate the divested business as an
effective competitor; and
(c) is sufficiently attractive to potential purchasers.
Conclusion on the effectiveness of full divestiture of HAS-Vent
Our conclusion therefore is that the divestment of the entire HAS-Vent business would be an effective remedy which would address the SLCs which we have identified, by restoring the status quo ante….Based on the evidence provided to us and assessed above, we have concluded that the following remedies would be effective in remedying the SLCs and adverse effects that we have found:
(a) Divestiture of one of the Parties’ sites in each of the SLC Areas; and
(b) Divestiture of the entire HAS-Vent business.
Assessment of proportionality of our preferred remedies
In order to be reasonable and proportionate, the CMA will seek to select the least
costly remedy, or package of remedies, that it considers will be effective. If the
CMA is choosing between two remedies which it considers will be equally
effective, it will select the remedy that imposes the least cost or that is least
intrusive or restrictive. In addition, the CMA will seek to ensure that no remedy is
disproportionate in relation to the SLC and its adverse effects.524
10.127 In conducting this proportionality assessment, we first consider if there are any
relevant costs attached to either effective remedy, ie whether the merger has or is
expected to result in any RCBs which would be lost if either of the effective
remedy options were implemented.
Assessment of relevant customer benefits
When deciding on remedies, the CMA may have regard to the effects of remedial
action on any RCBs.525 In this section, we consider whether there are any RCBs
(within the meaning of the Act) that should be taken into account in our remedy
assessment……An effective remedy to an SLC might be considered disproportionate if it prevents
the realisation of any RCBs arising from the Merger, where these benefits
outweigh the SLC and any resulting adverse effects. Insofar as these benefits
constitute RCBs for the purposes of the Act, the statutory framework allows us to
take them into account when we decide whether any remedy is proportionate.
10.130 RCBs that will be foregone due to the implementation of a particular remedy may
be considered as costs of that remedy. The CMA may modify a remedy to ensure
retention of RCBs or it may change its remedy selection. For instance, it may
decide to implement an alternative effective remedy which retains RCBs, or it may
decide that no remedy is appropriate….. Neither the Parties, nor any third parties have identified any potential RCBs to
which we should have regard under the Act. Nor did we identify any RCBs ourselves. Consequently, we have not modified our view of the appropriate remedies in light of RCBs
The proportionality of effective remedies
10.132 In our conclusions on remedy effectiveness above, we summarised our view on
which remedies would be effective in addressing the SLCs and the resulting
adverse effects. We set out below our assessment of, and conclusions on, which
of the two remedies discussed in this chapter would constitute a proportionate
remedy.
Framework for assessment of proportionality of merger remedies
if it is choosing between equally effective remedies, the CMA will select the remedy that imposes the least cost or that is least restrictive (we call this the ‘least onerous effective remedy’). In addition, the CMA will seek to ensure
that no remedy is disproportionate in relation to the SLC and its adverse effects….To facilitate this assessment, we first consider whether there are any relevant costs associated with each effective remedy option. When considering the costs of
an effective remedy, the CMA’s considerations may include (but are not limited to):
(a) distortions in market outcomes;
(b) compliance and monitoring costs incurred by the Parties, third parties, or the CMA; and
(c) the loss of any RCBs that may arise from the Merger which are foregone as a result of the remedy.
The CMA will generally attribute less significance to the costs of a remedy that will
be incurred by the merger parties than the costs that will be imposed by a remedy
on third parties, the CMA or other monitoring agencies.529 In particular, for
completed mergers, the CMA will not normally take account of costs or losses that
will be incurred by the merger parties as a result of a divestiture remedy, as it is for
the merger parties to assess whether there is a risk that a completed merger
would be subject to an SLC finding, and the CMA would expect this risk to be
reflected in the agreed acquisition price.
Having considered the least onerous effective remedy, we then consider whether
the least onerous remedy would be proportionate to the SLC and its adverse effects. In doing so, we compare the level of harm which is likely to arise from the SLC with the relevant costs of the proposed remedy
Identification of the least onerous, effective remedy
In considering the costs of each of the effective remedies (individual site
divestment and the full divestiture of HAS-Vent), we note that neither remedy
option imposes relevant costs beyond the divestiture process itself,536 and there
would be no market distortion, no costs to third parties, no costs to the CMA or
other monitoring agencies in ensuring compliance with the remedies and no loss
of RCBs. ….Although we find that both the sale of one of the Parties’ sites in each of the SLC
Areas, and the sale of the entire HAS-Vent business are effective remedies to the
SLCs which we identified, we note that the divestiture of the entire HAS-Vent
business would be a more intrusive remedy than is necessary to remedy the SLCs
(eg the sale of one of the Parties’ sites in each of the SLC Areas). Therefore, we
conclude that the sale of one of the Parties’ sites in each of the SLC Areas is the
least onerous, effective remedy
Proportionality to the SLC and its adverse effects
The CMA will seek to ensure that no remedy is disproportionate in relation to the
SLC and its adverse effects….. In this final report we have concluded that the Merger could lead to higher prices
and reduced choice for customers of the Parties in the local areas centred around
Nottingham and Stoke-on-Trent…… We have therefore compared the extent of harm associated with the SLCs with the
relevant costs of the least onerous effective remedy, and consider that requiring
the sale of one of the Parties’ sites in each of the SLC Areas would not be
disproportionate in relation to the SLC and its adverse effects
Conclusion on proportionality
Following this assessment and given the requirement on the CMA to impose the
least costly or least restrictive remedy where two remedies are found to be equally
effective (as is the case here), our view is that the divestiture of one of the Parties’
sites in each of the SLC Areas, is an effective and a proportionate remedy to the
SLCs we have found, and is the least intrusive of the two potential effective
remedy options.
We consider 6 months to be enough time to enable Lindab to complete the divestment of one of the Parties’ sites in each of the SLC Areas. Given that Lindab has a dedicated M&A team, extensive
M&A experience and itself considers that a divestiture process for one of the
Parties’ sites in each of the SLC Areas is non-complex and straightforward to
execute, we do not discount that Lindab may be able to conclude the divestiture
process within a period of less than [] months. However, a maximum divestiture
period of [] months will provide Lindab with some flexibility given that it will also
be reliant on timely engagement by potential purchasers.
While we understand that Lindab does not intend to run the type of formal sales
process which might be expected for larger transactions (including for example,
preparation of an information memorandum, collation of data for a data room etc),
Lindab has set out some key milestones which it envisages for the sales process
for the divestment sites…….. As explained earlier in this chapter, given that different manufacturing models are
adopted by different suppliers in the market for the supply of circular ducts and
fittings, by including or excluding manufacturing assets from the scope of the
divestiture package, the Parties may limit the pool of potential purchasers. On this
basis and as concluded earlier in this chapter, Lindab should be required to market
all four potential divestment sites for sale during the divestiture process (and to
publicise the option for potential purchasers to acquire one or two sites out of the
four potential divestment sites, including on its website, to ensure sufficient
visibility and awareness of the sales process).558 Depending on the outcome of
Lindab’s assessment, potential purchasers will then be invited to submit formal
expressions of interest for their preferred sites.
We note Lindab’s suggestion outlined at paragraph 10.155(b) that one or two
candidates will be selected or a shortlist drawn up. We consider that if Lindab only
puts forward one candidate per site or for both sites, this may result in a risk to the
sales process given: (i) that candidate may not be considered a suitable purchaser
by the CMA, and/or (ii) the potential for the one candidate to drop out of the sales
process which would derail the divestiture process. In order to avoid this risk,
Lindab may need to provide high-level information on the divestment sites to more
than one purchaser in order to ensure that a suitable purchaser can be proposed
as a prospective purchaser to the CMA for its approval.
The CMA’s investigation found that GXO and Wincanton compete closely, particularly for contracts with large retail customers. Although GXO will continue to face competition from other contract logistics providers, many of these are significantly smaller, or focus on specific industries or types of logistics services (such as transport). Although some businesses have the option to bring services in-house if contract logistics suppliers do not offer good value, the ability to do this varies by customer…..The CMA is therefore concerned that the deal could raise costs for businesses that rely on contract logistics suppliers to move goods around the UK and for other supply chain activities…..Contract logistics services are critical for the flow of goods around the country, reducing delays, and ensuring that products reach their destinations efficiently and reliably. These services are essential for millions of people who rely on timely deliveries or being able to buy products off the shelf.
This market is worth £16 billion in the UK, and we’re concerned that this merger could reduce competition, resulting in higher costs being passed down to consumers. We consider that these competition concerns warrant an in-depth Phase 2 investigation
cma decis to refer to phase2:
1.CMA has found that the acquisition by GXO Logistics, Inc. (GXO) of Wincanton plc (Wincanton) gives rise to a realistic prospect of a substantial lessening of competition (SLC) as a result of horizontal unilateral effects in the supply of mainstream contract logistics services (CLS) in the UK.
2. On 29 April 2024, GXO acquired Wincanton. The CMA refers to this acquisition as the Merger. GXO and Wincanton are together referred to as the Parties and, for statements relating to the future, the Merged Entity.
3. As the CMA has found that the Merger gives rise to a realistic prospect of an SLC, the Parties have until 8 November 2024 to offer undertakings in lieu of a reference (UILs) to the CMA that will remedy the competition concerns identified. If no such undertaking is offered, or the CMA decides that any undertaking offered is insufficient to remedy its concerns to the phase 1 standard, then the CMA will refer the Merger for an in-depth phase 2 investigation pursuant to sections 22(1) and 34ZA(2) of the Enterprise Act 2002 (the Act).
Who are the businesses and what products/services do they provide?
4. GXO and Wincanton both provide CLS including distribution and transport, warehousing, order fulfilment and other supply chain services to various types of customers.
5. The services that the CMA looked at in detail were the supply of mainstream CLS in the UK, comprising CLS to retail customers (eg fashion or groceries) and non-retail customers (eg public or chemicals) as this is the main overlap between the
Parties’ CLS activities.
The CMA believes that the Merger raises significant competition concerns as a result of horizontal unilateral effects in the supply of mainstream CLS. In particular:
(a) the Merger would materially increase the level of concentration in the market, with the Merged Entity and its two largest rivals accounting for a significant proportion of supply. The Merged Entity would become the largest mainstream CLS provider with a share of supply of [20-30]%, followed by DHL ([10-20]%), Culina ([10-20]%) and a tail of much smaller providers (all <5%)
(b) The Parties (along with DHL, and to a lesser extent, Culina) compete closely in the supply of mainstream CLS, particularly for larger retail customers with complex requirements (such as omni-channel retailers and those active in the groceries and fast-moving consumer goods sectors). A range of evidence, including tender data, customer evidence and internal documents suggests that these customers may have limited credible options and that both Parties are currently strong alternatives.
(c) Although there is a long tail of other mainstream CLS suppliers, many of these are very small, or specialise in supplying particular types of logisticsservice (eg transport) or particular industries (eg fashion and apparel). While the CMA has seen evidence that some of these suppliers constrain the Parties for particular types of opportunity, the evidence reviewed by the CMA at phase 1 does not suggest that individually or cumulatively they exert a sufficient constraint across the mainstream CLS market to prevent competition concerns from arising
(d) While a significant proportion of logistics are done by customers themselves (self-supply) the ability of customers to self-supply would impose only a weak competitive constraint on the Merged Entity as self-supply is not viable for a significant set of customers
https://www.reuters.com/markets/companies/IBE.MC
The (CMA) has decided to investigate this transaction and has made an initial enforcement order (IEO): for the purposes of preventing pre-emptive action in accordance with section 72(2) of the Act the CMA makes the following order addressed to Iberdrola SA, SPW Investments and SPENH (collectively Iberdrola), and NWEN Jersey and NWEN UK (collectively NWEN) ….
.Iberdrola, S.A is a Spanish multinational electric utility company based in Bilbao, Spain. It has around 40,000 employees and serves around 30 million customers. Subsidiaries include ScottishPower (United Kingdom) and a significant part of Avangrid (United States), amongst others. As of 2023, the largest shareholder of the company is the Qatar Investment Authority, with BlackRock and Norges Bank (managers of the Norwegian Government Pension Fund Global) also holding significant interests. Iberdrola is the largest producer of wind power, and the world’s second largest electricity utility by market capitalisation. As of 2023, the company operates a capacity of 62,045 MW, of which 41,246 MW are from renewable sources worldwide
MNO Mobile Network Operator MOCN Multi-operator core network – a technology that allows two or more core networks to share the same RAN.MORAN multi-operator radio access networkMVNO Mobile Virtual Network Operator . RCBs Relevant customer benefits REEs Rivalry-enhancing efficiencies. RFI Request for information. SRN = shared rural network scheme.
CMA conclusion
The least costly and intrusive remedy/ When selecting a remedy, the CMA must select the least costly and intrusiveremedy, or package of remedies, of those remedy options that it considers will be effective. With respect to the costs of prohibition of the Merger, we have found that prohibition would leave the market structure unchanged and therefore does not cause distortions in outcomes. The implementation of the remedy would not give rise to compliance and monitoring costs. We have also found that the extent of benefits that are appropriate to take into account as RCBs for the purposes of the Act are not significant when set against the adverse effects of the Merger. Therefore, we consider there are only limited costs associated with prohibition of the Merger……However, we acknowledge that prohibition is an intrusive remedy, as it would prevent the proposed Merger from completing….. With respect to the Network Commitment and Time Limited Protections, we have found that while the remedy would require the CMA and Ofcom to incur monitoring costs, these would not be significant, and while there are some distortion risks, these are limited…… The Network Commitment and Time Limited protections would be a less intrusive remedy as it would allow the Parties to complete the Merger. CMA87, paragraphs 3.4 and 3.6. Given our provisional conclusions that none of the costs associated with the remedies are significant when set against the adverse effects of the Merger, our proportionality framework requires us to select the less intrusive remedy. The package consisting of the Network Commitment and Time Limited Protections is therefore our preferred remedy option. 1.574 If the Parties are not willing to offer an Undertaking giving effect to the Network Commitment and Time Limited Protections as outlined in this working paper, we provisionally consider that prohibition would be the only available effective remedyand the CMA would seek to impose an Order prohibiting the Merger. Proportionality of the Network Commitment and Time Limited Protections in relation to the SLC and its adverse effects1.575 Having identified the least costly and intrusive effective remedy, we then consider whether this remedy would be disproportionate to the SLC and its resulting adverse effects. In doing so, we compare the extent of harm associated with the SLCs with the relevant costs of our preferred remedy outlined above. 1.576 Absent remedial action, the provisional SLCs can be expected to lead to price increases for mobile customers (or to equivalent reductions in data packages or service features) affecting tens of millions of mobile users in the UK. We also consider that absent remedial action the Merged Entity – and its competitors – may have less of an incentive to bid for wholesale business and/or may offer less competitive prices/terms to MVNOs. 1.577 As set out above, we consider the costs of the Network Commitment and Time Limited Protections to be limited. The remedy is also not intrusive as it would enable the Parties to complete the Merger. Therefore, we provisionally conclude that our preferred remedy is not disproportionate to the SLC and its adverse effects.Proportionality of prohibition in relation to the SLC and its adverse effects1.578 As set out above, if the Parties are not willing to offer an Undertaking giving effect to the Network Commitment and Time Limited Protections as outlined in this working paper, we provisionally consider that prohibition would be the only available effective remedy and the CMA would seek to impose an Order prohibiting the Merger……. Therefore, we have also considered whether prohibition of the Merger would be disproportionate to the SLC and its resulting adverse effects. As set out above, the provisional SLCs can be expected to lead to price increases for mobile customers (or to equivalent reductions in data packages or service 131features) affecting tens of millions of mobile users in the UK. We also consider that absent remedial action the Merged Entity – and its competitors – may have less of an incentive to bid for wholesale business and/or may offer less competitive prices/terms to MVNOs.1.581 We have also provisionally found that any RCBs that would be lost as a result of prohibition of the Merger would not be significant when set against the adverse effects of the Merger (see paragraphs 1.562). The loss of RCBs is the only cost we have provisionally identified associated with prohibition of the Merger (see paragraph 1.545a). Therefore, in the absence of any less costly and intrusive alternative effective remedy, we consider that prohibition of the Merger would not be disproportionate to the SLC and its adverse effects. Provisional conclusion on proportionality ……We have provisionally identified two effective remedies:(a) Prohibition of the Merger; and(b) The Network Commitment supported by Time Limited Protections.We identified the relevant costs associated with each of those remedies and provisionally concluded that:(a) The only relevant costs in the case of prohibition of the Merger are the loss of RCBs. Any RCBs within the meaning of the Act that would be lost as a result of prohibition of the Merger would not be significant when set against the adverse effects of the Merger. (b) The Network Commitment and Time Limited Protections give rise to monitoring costs for the CMA and Ofcom, and limited distortion risks but, overall, these are limited. We are required, as per our guidance, to select the least costly and intrusiveremedy we consider to be effective. We consider that neither remedy incurs significant costs when set against the adverse effects of the Merger, but that prohibition of the Merger is more intrusive. We therefore consider that the Network Commitment supported by Time Limited Protections is more proportionate than prohibition of the Merger. We consider the Network Commitment supported by Time Limited Protections would not be disproportionate to the SLC and its adverse effects. We further consider that, in the absence of any less costly and intrusive alternative effective remedy – which would be the case if the Parties are not willing to offer an Undertaking giving effect to the Network Commitment and Time Limited Protections as outlined in this working paper – prohibition of the Merger would not be disproportionate to the SLC and its adverse effects.Provisional decision on remedies….. We have provisionally concluded that there are two effective, proportionate remedies that would comprehensively address the provisional SLCs in the retail and wholesale markets outlined in the Provisional Findings. These are: (a) Prohibition of the Merger; and(b) Network Commitment (with the Time Limited Protections described above in the retail and wholesale markets). Our preferred remedy is the Network Commitment supported by the Time Limited Protections, this being the least costly and intrusive effective remedy that is notdisproportionate in relation to the SLC and its adverse effects we have provisionally identified……If the Parties are not willing to offer an Undertaking giving effect to the Network Commitment and Time Limited Protections as described in this working paper, as the only other effective remedy, we would seek to impose an Order prohibiting the Merger
CMA reasoning:
we provisionally found that the Merger may be expected to give rise to an SLC in two markets:(a) An SLC as a result of horizontal unilateral effects in the retail market. In particular, we provisionally found in relation to this theory of harm that the Merger would lead to price increases for mobile customers (or to equivalent reductions in data packages or service features). Any price increases would 5 potentially affect tens of millions of mobile customers, and we had particular concerns about the impact of the Merger on those customers least able to afford mobile services or who might have to pay more for improvements in service quality they do not value.(b) An SLC as a result of horizontal unilateral effects in the wholesale market. In particular, we provisionally found in relation to this theory of harm that the Merged Entity – and its competitors – may have less of an incentive to bid for wholesale business and/or may offer less competitive prices/terms to mobile virtual network operators (MVNOs). In particular, the Merger would reduce the number of mobile network operators (MNOs) from four to three, making it more difficult for independent MVNOs to secure attractive competitive terms which would reduce their ability to compete strongly in the retail market. We considered that this was important because many MVNOs price aggressively, often focusing on value segments of the retail market.1.10 When announcing the Merger, the Parties made a number of claims about procompetitive efficiencies and consumer benefits which they said would result from the Merger. For example, they said that from ‘Day 1’ (ie within the first 12 months from closing the Merger) millions of customers of VUK and 3UK would enjoy a better network experience with greater coverage and reliability at no extra cost. They also said that the combined business would invest GBP 11 billion in the UK over ten years to create one of Europe’s most advanced 5G SA networks, and that the Merger would create a third mobile operator with scale, levelling the competitive playing field, and thereby increasing competition to the UK’s two leading converged operators (BT Group plc (BTEE) and VMED O2 UK Limited(VMO2)).41.11 Part way through the phase 2 investigation, the Parties entered into an agreement with VMO2 (Beacon 4.1) which involves, among other things, the divestment of spectrum to VMO2 (conditional on CMA approval of the Merger). The Parties submitted that Beacon 4.1 would generate further Merger-specific efficiencies, in particular by making VMO2 a more effective competitor in the wholesale and retail markets.5 1.12 The Parties submitted that through the integration of and investment in the Parties’ two networks and Beacon 4.1 the Merger would give rise to substantial rivalry enhancing efficiencies (REEs), which would offset any potential anti-competitive effects of the Merger. In the course of the merger review process, the Parties also supplied us with a number of economic models and submissions.
….but… In our Provisional Findings, we provisionally concluded that the Merger is likely to result in some level of network quality improvements which are rivalry enhancing.6However, we also provisionally concluded that the Parties – given their ability to pursue a range of commercial strategies, which may evolve over time in response to changing market circumstances – were not likely to deliver the full JBP.7 We also considered that the spectrum transfer to VMO2 agreed through Beacon 4.1 would provide a notable and rapid increase in network quality for VMO2’swholesale and retail customers which would further increase network quality competition.8 On the basis of the evidence and analysis at the date of our Provisional Findings, we provisionally concluded that the increased rivalry from those efficiencies which we found were likely to be realised was not sufficient to outweigh the adverse impacts identified in relation to the retail and wholesale markets.9 1.15 We also expressed some doubts whether the full JBP would – if delivered – offset the anti-competitive effects of the provisionally identified SLCs. We invited submissions from the Parties and third parties in this respect, but we did not need to provisionally conclude on that question in our Provisional Findings.
in Ecolab v cma , in cat , was appealed to the Court of Appeal (coa) has explained that, once the CMA has reached a conclusion on the SLC question, ‘then the action which it has to take must be such as to remedy or prevent the SLC concerned. further, the coa held : that it is reasonable for the CMA to not favour a remedy for which it could not feel a ‘high degree of confidence of success’
Remedy types:
(a) Structural remedies (preferred by cma in most cases) such as prohibition and divestiture, are generally one-off measures that seek to restore or maintain the competitive structure of the market by addressing the market participants and/or their shares of the market
(b) Behavioural remedies (ex network commitments) are ongoing measures that are designed to regulate or constrain the behaviour of merger parties. the Merger Remedies Guidance also says that ‘[b]ehavioural remedies can operate satisfactorily in limited circumstances, especially where the company operates in a regulated environment and where there are expert monitors…..he design of behavioural remedies seeks to avoid four particular forms of risk to enable these measures to be as effective as possible:184(a) Specification risks: these risks arise if the form of conduct required to address the SLC or its adverse effects cannot be specified with sufficient clarity to provide an effective basis for monitoring and compliance. (b) Circumvention risk: as behavioural remedies generally do not deal with the source of an SLC, it is possible that other adverse forms of behaviour may arise if particular forms of behaviour are restricted.(c) Distortion risks: these are risks that behavioural remedies may create market distortions that reduce the effectiveness of these measures and/or increase their effective costs. (d) Monitoring and enforcement risks: for behavioural remedies to have the desired impact, it is essential that there are effective and adequately resourced arrangements in place for monitoring and enforcement.
A number of third parties – in response to the Remedies Notice – submitted thatoutcomes in other countries suggest behavioural remedies are ineffective and should not be considered further. Other third parties and the Parties also submitted comparative assessments of the potential remedies considered in this case with previous remedies accepted in other countries in the mobile telecommunications industry, in particular in the context of four-to-three MNO mergers…..BUT….. The CMA’s Merger Assessment Guidelines, reflecting the relevant case law, notes that the CMA’s task in analysing mergers is case-specific.
a divestiture remedy would need to enable a suitable purchaser to compete effectively under separate ownership. However, a purchaser would likely only acquire a sub-set of the assets currently used by the Parties to compete in the relevant markets. This may lead to an MNO that is smaller than either of the Parties today. It is not clear that such an entity would be able to compete effectively in both the retail and wholesale markets where we have provisionally identified SLCs….further, Ofcom also noted that divestiture remedies in the mobile sector have been relatively unsuccessful in restoring a fourth operator and noted that regardless how much spectrum is divested, it remains difficult for the remedy taker to gain market share. One example of the challenges is that the Parties do not own all of thenetwork infrastructure they use, often using neutral hosts (or tower companies) which build passive infrastructure (such as towers and masts). The Parties, and not the CMA, would therefore need to negotiate approval from these third partyinfrastructure providers to allow a new MNO to enter. ….We therefore consider that due to the above risks and practical difficulties an MNO entrant remedy would be high risk in the UK and would not present a sufficient degree of certainty of achieving its intended effect, ie the entry of a new MNO that compensates for the loss of competition resulting from the Merger…..Furthermore, the Parties have expressly stated that they would not consider a partial divestiture remedy, stating that it is commercially unacceptable and would not be accepted under any circumstances.
regarding a possible remedy involving an MVNO becoming an MNO through a partial divestiture, although we consider that the entry of further MVNOs and/or expansion of existing MVNOs might increase competition in the retail market, we consider it unlikely that this type of remedy would comprehensively address our retail concerns, as it would not compensate for the loss of an independent MNO. MVNOs cannot, to a large extent, compete on network quality. Overall, we consider that MVNOs do not offer the same competitive constraint as MNOs in the retail market…… Further, is unlikely that any entry of a new rival (buyer of any divestment remedy) into the wholesale market, would exert a material competitive constraint as a fourth competitor, and could even have material distortive effects on the wholesale market
consideration of possible Ring-fenced capacity remedies:
capacity ring-fencing remedy is an enabling behavioural remedy, as it seeks to create an incentive for the Parties to continue to compete in the wholesale market. this type of ringfencing remedy could either be delivered through a contractual arrangement (ie a commercial reservation remedy) or through a technical segregation of capacity. ex: a commercial reservation combined with a penalty to incentivise the Merged Entity to enter into MVNO agreements….. In the Remedies Notice we invited views on a remedy that seeks to ring-fence a proportion of the Parties’ network capacity exclusively for wholesale customers.89We considered that at the conceptual level, reserving a defined proportion of the Merged Entity’s capacity exclusively for MVNOs could add to the incentive of the Merged Entity to compete for MVNO customers. As MVNOs provide an important source of competition for more price-sensitive customers, it is possible that a ringfencing remedy could also benefit competition in the retail market……Ofcom told us that it should in principle be possible to contractually ring fence capacity whilst allowing all access to the same speeds. For instance, the contract could specify that the MVNOs could access ‘X’ gigabytes (GB), and adjust ‘X’ as the total network capacity grows.99 However, Ofcom has raised concerns that contractual capacity ring-fencing could lead to inefficiencies linked with the difficulties of planning how much capacity would need to be ringfenced………Alternatively, a ring-fencing remedy could be delivered through a technical separation of a determined proportion of the Merged Entity’s capacity. The Parties consider ring-fencing to be an inefficient use of capacity which would eliminate, or at the very least materially reduce, the efficiencies and benefits that the Parties claim will be realised as a result of the Merger.103 Ofcom also told us that technical ringfencing would be inefficient, as it reduces the speeds available to both sets of customers (the MVNOs’ and the MNOs’) and overall reduces the capacity available (or more precisely, results in more congestion for any given level of total traffic).104 Further the Parties estimated that such a technical implementation of a ring-fencing remedy (which would require the Merged Entity to have a 5G SA coreto enable a network ‘slice’ to be ring-fenced) would not be technically feasible until at least three years after completion of the Merger
consideration of poss.merger blocking:
Parties’ and third parties’ views on effectiveness of Merger prohibition1.100 The Parties submitted that prohibition of the Merger would have severe adverse effects on the development of competition in the retail and wholesale markets as the UK’s mobile markets would remain trapped in a low investment, low competition equilibrium.106 They submitted that prohibition would result in the loss of the REEs / RCBs generated by Merger, which represent billions of pounds in value to the UK